What Happens During Recessions,
Crunches and Busts?
Stijn Claessens, M. Ayhan Kose, and Marco E. Terrones
WP/08/274
© 2008 International Monetary Fund WP/08/274
IMF Working Paper
Research Department
What Happens During Recessions, Crunches and Busts?
Prepared by Stijn Claessens, M. Ayhan Kose and Marco E. Terrones
1
December 2008
Abstract
This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF.
The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent
those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are
published to elicit comments and to further debate.
We provide a comprehensive empirical characterization of the linkages between key
macroeconomic and financial variables around business and financial cycles for 21 OECD
countries over the period 1960–2007. In particular, we analyze the implications of 122
recessions, 112 (28) credit contraction (crunch) episodes, 114 (28) episodes of house price
declines (busts), 234 (58) episodes of equity price declines (busts) and their various overlaps
in these countries over the sample period. Our results indicate that interactions between
macroeconomic and financial variables can play major roles in determining the severity and
duration of recessions. Specifically, we find evidence that recessions associated with credit
crunches and house price busts tend to be deeper and longer than other recessions.
JEL Classification Numbers: E32; E44; E51; F42
Keywords: Business cycles, recessions, credit crunches, house prices, equity prices, busts
Authors E-Mail Address: scl[email protected]; akose@imf.org; [email protected]
1
We are grateful for helpful comments from Lewis Alexander, Michael Dooley, Kristin Forbes,
Prakash Loungani, and our discussants, Steven Kamin, Desmond Lachman, Vincent Reinhart, and
Angel Ubide, and participants at various seminars and conferences where earlier versions of this
paper were presented. Dio Kaltis, David Low, Yongjoon Shin and Zhi (George) Yu provided
excellent research assistance.
2
Contents Page
Executive Summary...................................................................................................................4
Figure A. What Happens During Recessions: Crunches and Busts? ........................................6
I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................7
II. Database and Methodology.................................................................................................10
A. Database..................................................................................................................10
B. Methodology ...........................................................................................................11
III. What Happens During Recessions?...................................................................................14
A. Basic Features of Recessions: Duration and Cost...................................................14
B. Changes in Macroeconomic and Financial Variables.............................................16
C. Dynamics of Recessions..........................................................................................17
D. Synchronization of Recessions, Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines.....18
IV. What Happens During Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines? ............................20
A. Episodes of Credit Contractions .............................................................................20
B. Episodes of Declines in House Prices.....................................................................22
C. Episodes of Declines in Equity Prices.....................................................................23
D. Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines: A Summary...................................24
V. What Happens During Recessions Associated with Crunches and Busts?.........................24
A. Recessions Associated with Credit Crunches .........................................................25
B. Recessions Associated with House Price Busts ......................................................25
C. Recessions Associated with Equity Price Busts......................................................26
D. Recessions Associated with Crunches and Busts: A Summary..............................27
VI. Recessions Associated with Increases in Oil Prices ..........................................................28
VII. Policy Responses During Recessions, Crunches and Busts.............................................29
VIII. Recession Outcomes and Financial Factors....................................................................30
IX. Conclusion.........................................................................................................................34
A. A Summary .............................................................................................................34
B. Lessons for Today ...................................................................................................34
C. Caveats and Future Research ..................................................................................35
References................................................................................................................................36
Figures
1. Associations Between Recessions, Crunches and Busts......................................................43
2. Recessions: Duration and Amplitude...................................................................................44
3. Recessions in OECD Countries ...........................................................................................45
4. Synchronization of Recessions ............................................................................................48
5. Synchronization of Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines......................................49
3
6. Credit Crunches in OECD Countries...................................................................................50
7. House Price Busts in OECD Countries................................................................................52
8. Equity Price Busts in OECD Countries ...............................................................................54
Tables
1A. Recessions: Summary Statistics........................................................................................56
1B. Recessions: Summary Statistics........................................................................................57
2A. Credit Contractions: Basic Statistics.................................................................................58
2B. Credit Contractions: Basic Statistics.................................................................................59
3A. House Price Declines: Basic Statistics..............................................................................60
3B. House Price Declines: Basic Statistics..............................................................................61
4A. Equity Price Declines: Basic Statistics .............................................................................62
4B. Equity Price Declines: Basic Statistics..............................................................................63
5. Credit Contractons and Asset Price Declines: Summary Statistics ...................................64
6. Leads and Lags: Recessions, Crunches and Busts............................................................65
7. Recessions Associated with Credit Crunches...................................................................66
8. Recessions Associated with House Price Busts ...............................................................67
9. Recessions Associated with Equity Price Busts ...............................................................68
10. Recessions Associated with Crunches and Busts: Summary Statistics ............................69
11. Recessions Associated with Oil Price Shocks ..................................................................70
12. Changes in Poicy Variables ..............................................................................................71
13A.Cost of Recessions ...........................................................................................................72
13B.Cost of Recessions ...........................................................................................................73
14A.Cost of Recessions ...........................................................................................................74
14B.Cost of Recessions ...........................................................................................................75
Appendix: Database ................................................................................................................41
4
Executive Summary
The current financial turmoil that started in the United States, initially led by sharp declines
in house prices, has transformed into a severe credit crunch with substantial losses in equity
markets. Moreover, it has now spread to a number of advanced and emerging countries, and
become the most severe global financial crisis since the Great Depression. This has led to an
intensive debate about how much the crisis will impact the real economy. There are already
indications that the spillovers from the difficulties in financial sector to economic activity
will not be mild — in fact, activity in the United States and several other advanced
economies has been contracting in recent months.
These developments have highlighted a number of questions about the linkages between the
financial sector and the real economy during recessions. Two specific questions that have
often been raised in the context of this debate are: How do macroeconomic and financial
variables behave around recessions, credit crunches and asset (house and equity) price busts?
And are recessions associated with credit crunches and asset price busts different than other
recessions?
In order to address these questions, we provide a comprehensive empirical characterization
of the linkages between key macroeconomic and financial variables around business and
financial cycles for 21 OECD countries over the 1960-2007 period. In particular, we analyze
the implications of 122 recessions, 112 (28) credit contraction (crunch) episodes, 114 (28)
episodes of house price declines (busts), and 234 (58) episodes of equity price declines
(busts) in these countries over the sample period, their implications and various overlaps. The
main results are as follows:
The typical recession lasts almost 4 quarters and is associated with an output drop of
roughly 2 percent (Figure A). Most macroeconomic and financial variables exhibit
procyclical behavior during recessions. While recessions have been becoming shorter and
milder over time, they remain highly synchronized across countries. Moreover, recessions
often coincide with the episodes of contractions in domestic credit and declines in asset
prices.
Episodes of credit crunches, house price and equity price busts last much longer than
recessions do. For example, a credit crunch episode typically lasts two-and-a-half years and
is associated with nearly a 20 percent decline in credit. A housing bust tends to persist even
longer—four-and-a-half years with a 30 percent fall in real house prices. And an equity price
bust lasts some 10 quarters and when it is over, the real value of equities drops by half.
In one out of six recessions, there is also a credit crunch underway, and in one out of
four recessions a house price bust. Equity price busts coincide with one-third of recession
episodes. There can be considerable lags between financial market disturbances and real
activity. A recession, if one occurs, can start as late as four to five quarters after the onset of a
credit crunch or housing bust.
5
Most importantly, recessions associated with credit crunches and house price busts
are deeper and last longer than other recessions do. In particular, although recessions
accompanied with severe credit crunches or house price busts last only three months longer,
they typically result in output losses two to three times greater than recessions without such
financial stresses. There is also evidence that the extent of declines in house prices appears to
influence the depth of recessions, even after accounting for the changes in other financial
variables, including credit and equity prices, and various other controls. These findings
suggest that the strength of linkages between the financial sector and the real economy can
aggravate output losses during recessions.
The lessons from the earlier episodes of recessions, crunches and busts we examined
are sobering, suggesting that recessions following the current crisis will likely be more costly
than other recessions because they take place alongside simultaneous credit crunches and
asset price busts. Furthermore, although the effects of the current crisis have already been felt
around the world, the past evidence suggests that its global dimensions are likely to intensify
in the coming months.
6
Figure A. What Happens During Recessions, Crunches and Busts?
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
All Recessions
Severe Recessions
GDP Growth
(in percent)
Duration
(Number of Quarters)
R
ecessions can be long and deep...
0
20
40
60
1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
GDP
Credit
fraction of countries in recession/credit contraction,
in percent
-8
-6
-4
-2
0
Without a Crunch/Bust
With a Crunch/Bust
With a Severe Crunch/Bust
Credit Crunch
(GDP Loss, in percent)
House Price Bust
(GDP Loss, in percent)
Credit-crunch and house-price-bust recessions
are usually deeper
-40
-30
-20
-10
0
10
20
30
Credit Crunch
House Price Bust
Duration
(Number of Quarters)
Credit/House Price
Growth
(in percent)
Crunches and busts are typically long with
s
ubstantial declines in credit and house price
… and highly synchronized across countries and
often coincide with credit contractions
Notes: GDP growth is the percent change in the level of output during the recession period. Severe
recessions refer to those in which the peak-to-trough decline in output is in the top quartile of all
recession-related output declines. Synchronization is measured by the fraction of countries experiencing a
recession or a credit contraction at the same time. GDP loss is the total amount of GDP lost between the
peak and trough of a recession. Severe credit crunches and house price busts are those that are in the top
half of all crunch and bust episodes.
7
“… recessions that follow swings in asset prices are not necessarily longer, deeper,
and associated with a greater fall in output and investment than other recessions…”
Roger W. Ferguson, Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, January 2005
“If we do end up dating the recession as beginning at the
end of last year, it could be a very long
recession.”
Martin Feldstein, Member of the NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee, August 2008
I. I
NTRODUCTION
The financial turmoil that started in the United States last year has now spread to a number of
advanced and emerging countries and transformed into the most severe global financial crisis
since the Great Depression. This has led to an intensive debate about how much the financial
crisis will impact the broader economies. There are already indications that the spillovers
from the financial crisis to the real economy will not be mild—in fact, activity in the United
States and several other advanced economies has been contracting in recent months.
These developments have highlighted a number of questions about the linkages between the
real economy and the financial sector during recessions. Two specific questions that have
often been raised in the context of this debate are: How do macroeconomic and financial
variables behave around recessions, credit crunches and asset (house and equity) price busts?
And are recessions associated with credit crunches and asset price busts different than other
recessions? In order to address these questions, we provide a comprehensive empirical
characterization of the linkages between key macroeconomic and financial variables around
business and financial cycles for 21 OECD countries over the 1960-2007 period.
We first identify turning points in these variables using standard business cycle dating
methods. We document 122 recessions, 112 credit contractions, 114 house price declines,
and 234 equity price declines for these countries over the sample period. When recessions,
credit contractions, house price and equity price declines fall into the top quartiles of all
recessions, contractions and declines, we define them as severe recessions, credit crunches,
house price busts and equity price busts, respectively. We then analyze the characteristics of
these events—in terms of their duration and severity—and the behavior of major
macroeconomic and financial variables around the various cycles.
With respect to the first question, we find that the typical recession lasts almost 4 quarters
and is associated with an output drop (decline from peak to trough) of roughly 2 percent.
Severe recessions are, by construction, much more costly, with a median decline of about
5 percent, and last a quarter longer. While typical recessions tend to result in a cumulative
loss of around 3 percent, severe ones cost three times more. As one would expect, most
macroeconomic and financial variables exhibit procyclical behavior during recessions. In
addition, recessions are characterized by sharp declines in (residential) investment, industrial
production, imports, and housing and equity prices, modest declines in consumption and
exports, and some decrease in employment rates. Two key policy related variables—short-
term interest rates and fiscal expenditures—often behave countercyclical during recessions.
8
For some observers, the global nature of the current crisis has been unprecedented, as several
advanced economies have simultaneously experienced difficulties in their credit markets as
well as declines in their house and equity prices. However, these recent phenomena are not
unusual because historically recessions, crunches and busts often occur at the same time
across countries. Indeed, recessions in many advanced countries were bunched in four
periods over the past 40 years—the mid-70s, the early 80s, the early 90s and the early-
2000s—and often coincided with global shocks. Just as many countries experience
synchronized recessions, countries also go through simultaneous episodes of credit
contractions. Moreover, declines in house and equity prices tend to occur at the same time.
Our findings indicate that the episodes of credit crunches, house price and equity price busts
last much longer than recessions do. For example, the average duration of a credit crunch is
around 10 quarters while an asset price bust is usually even longer, with an average duration
of 18 (12) quarters in the case of house (equity) price busts. The dynamics of the main
components of domestic absorption around these events are similar to those observed during
recessions. A much larger decline in the growth rate of investment compared with that of
consumption is a feature of both recessions as well as credit crunches and house price busts.
In particular, episodes of credit crunch and house price bust are accompanied with large
declines in residential investment. There is also evidence that credit crunches and house price
busts are more costly than equity price busts, as equity price busts are less consistently
associated with real sector outcomes.
For the second question, we document the coincidence of recessions with credit crunches or
asset price busts. In about one out of six recessions, there is also a credit crunch underway
and, in about one out of four recessions, also a house price bust. Equity price busts overlap
for about one-third of recession episodes. A recession, if one occurs, can start as late as four
to five quarters after the onset of a credit crunch or an asset bust.
In terms of duration and severity, we find that recessions associated with housing busts and
credit crunches are both deeper and longer-lasting than other recessions are. Differences in
total output loss between events with severe crunches and busts and those without typically
amount to one percentage point, while the duration is more than one quarter longer in case of
a housing bust. In terms of the behavior of key macroeconomic and financial variables, we
find that residential investment tends to fall more sharply in recessions with housing busts
and in those with credit crunches than in other recessions. Unemployment rates increase
notably more in recessions with housing busts.
In addition to our event study of interactions among various macroeconomic and financial
variables during recessions accompanied with (or without) credit crunches or asset price
busts, we also conduct a more formal analysis of the depth of recessions and the special roles
played by changes in financial market conditions during these episodes. In particular, we
employ a basic regression framework to examine how the amplitude of a recession is
associated with changes in financial variables during recessions. Our results suggest that the
changes in house prices tend to be the financial variable most robustly associated with the
depth of recessions. Besides by its duration, the extent of decline in output is most influenced
by the state of the economy at the onset of the recession.
9
Our study contributes to a large body of research analyzing the roles played by financial
variables in explaining fluctuations in economic activity. Financial and macroeconomic
variables closely interact through wealth and substitution effects, and through the impact they
have on the balance sheets of firms and households (see, for instance, Blanchard and Fischer,
1989; and Obstfeld and Rogoff, 1999). In particular, asset prices can, by affecting household
wealth, influence consumption, and by altering a firm’s net worth and the market value of the
capital stock relative to its replacement value, influence investment. Perhaps more
importantly, the interactions between the financial sector and the real economy can be
amplified through the financial accelerator and related mechanisms. According to these
mechanisms, an increase in asset prices improves a firm’s (or household’s) net worth,
enhancing its capacities to borrow, invest and spend. This process can in turn lead to further
increases in asset prices and have general equilibrium effects.
2
Various empirical studies—both macro- and microeconomic—have been able to provide
evidence for these channels.
3
For example, there is a large empirical literature analyzing the
dynamics of business cycles, asset price fluctuations and credit cycles (Bernanke and Gertler,
1989; Borio, Furfine and Lowe, 2001). This literature, however, mainly analyzes the general
procyclicality of financial and macroeconomic variables, and less so how interactions
between financial and real economic variables vary during recessions, which is our focus.
We also contribute to a branch of the large literature on business cycles which aims to
identify the turning points in macroeconomic and financial variables using various
methodologies. The classical methodology of dating business cycles we use here finds its
roots in the pioneering work of Burns and Mitchell (1946) and has been widely used over the
years (Harding and Pagan, 2006). Morsink, Helbling, and Tokarick (2002), for example,
employ this methodology to analyze the main features of recessions and recoveries in a
number of OECD countries. Fewer studies have conducted cross-country analyses of cycles
in asset prices identified by this method.
4
One example is Helbling and Terrones (2003)
which examines the implications of asset price booms and busts in a large set of industrial
countries and conclude that house price busts are typically more costly than equity price
busts are.
Although the roles played by financial variables in business cycles have thus received much
attention from various theoretical and empirical perspectives, most of these studies have
considered the topics of business cycle, credit and asset prices independently (or in isolation).
Furthermore, the links between real and financial variables during recessions have yet to be
2
Some of the seminal models with these general equilibrium dynamics include Bernanke and Gertler
(1989) and Kiyotaki and Moore (1997) followed by extensions of these models that also have
dynamics which resemble Fisher’s (1933) debt-deflation mechanism. Mendoza (2008) uses this
framework to examine sudden stops in small open economies.
3
Studies using micro data (banks or corporations) include Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1996) and
Kashyap and Stein (2000).
4
Other such studies include Borio and McGuire (2004) and Pagan and Sossounov (2003). Terrones
(2004) studies the synchronization of house prices and the interaction between housing markets and
the real economy using dynamic factor models.
10
analyzed using a comprehensive dataset of a large number of countries over a long period of
time. Besides analysis that was limited in number of cases and some other, “case-type”
studies of individual episodes, or studies that focused specifically on the behavior of real and
financial variables surrounding financial crises, notably Reinhart and Rogoff (2008), to the
best of our knowledge, there is no comprehensive empirical analysis of these links.
5
Our paper thus fills three gaps in the literature. First, we examine the implications of
episodes of recessions, credit crunches, house and equity price busts for a large set of
macroeconomic and financial variables for a sizeable number of countries over a long period
of time. Second, our study is the first detailed, cross-country empirical analysis addressing
the implications of recessions when they coincide with certain types of financial market
difficulties, including credit crunches, house price busts and equity price busts. Third, we
provide some preliminary evidence suggesting that the change in house prices during
recessions appears to be an important factor influencing the cost of recessions.
The paper is structured as follows. In section II, we briefly present the data and methodology
we use. Next, we examine the basic characteristics of recessions in Section III. Then, we
consider how the key macroeconomic and financial variables behave around the episodes of
credit contractions (and crunches) and asset price declines (and busts) in Section IV. We
study the implications of recessions associated with crunches and asset price busts in
Section V. In Section VI, we briefly analyze the outcomes of recessions accompanied with
large increases in oil prices. This is followed by a short discussion of the changes in policy
variables during various episodes of recessions, crunches and busts in Section VII.
Section VIII presents a more formal analysis of the roles played by financial factors in
determining the cost of recessions using some simple regression models. Section IX
concludes.
II. DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY
A. Database
We construct a comprehensive database of macroeconomic and financial variables for 21
OECD countries over the period 1960:1-2007:4, mostly from the IMF International Financial
Statistics (IFS) and OECD Analytical Databases.
6
We focus our analysis on the following
macroeconomic variables: output, consumption, investment, residential investment, non-
residential investment, industrial production, exports, imports, net exports, current account
balance, and the unemployment and inflation rate. The quarterly time series of
5
Ferguson (2005) considered, in the aftermath of the collapse of the internet bubble, the links
between asset prices, credit and business cycles for three episodes with rapid asset price increases and
credit expansions, followed by subsequent recessions: the United Kingdom in 1974, Japan in 1992,
and the United States in 2001.
6
The countries in our sample are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France,
Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain,
Switzerland, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
11
macroeconomic variables are seasonally adjusted, whenever necessary, and in constant
prices.
The financial variables we consider are credit, house prices and equity prices. Credit series
are obtained from the IFS and defined as claims on the private sector by deposit money
banks. The main source for house prices is the Bank for International Settlements (BIS).
Equity price indices are also from the IFS. All financial variables are converted into real
terms by deflating them by the respective consumer price index (CPI).
The “policy” variables we focus on are government consumption, as a proxy for fiscal policy,
and short-term interest rates, as a proxy for monetary policy. The series for government
consumption are obtained from the OECD Analytical Database. The short-term interest rates
are from the IFS, Haver Analytics and Datastream. We consider the short-term interest rates
both in nominal and real terms, with the nominal rates deflated using the CPI to arrive at the
real rates. Government consumption is also deflated using the CPI. We list the detailed
sources and definitions of each of these variables in Appendix I.
B. Methodology
Much research has been devoted to the definition and measurement of business cycles
(Harding and Pagan, 2006). Our study is based on the “classical” definition of a business
cycle mainly because of its simplicity, but also because it constitutes the guiding principle of
the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) in determining the turning points of
U.S. business cycles. The definition itself goes back to the pioneering work of Burns and
Mitchell (1946) who laid the methodological foundation for the analysis of business cycles
in the United States.
In particular, they define a cycle to “consist[s] of expansions occurring at about the same
time in many economic activities, followed by similar general recessions, contractions, and
revivals which merge into the expansion phase of the next cycle; this sequence of changes is
recurrent but not periodic; in duration, business cycles vary from more than one year to ten
or twelve years.” Following the spirit of this broad characterization of a business cycle, the
NBER (2001) defines a recession as “a significant decline in activity spread across the
economy, lasting more than a few months, visible in industrial production, employment, real
income, and wholesale-retail trade. A recession begins just after the economy reaches a peak
of activity and ends as the economy reaches its trough.”
The classical methodology focuses on changes in the level of economic activity to identify
business cycles. As an alternative methodology, one can consider how economic activity
fluctuates around a trend by employing a method that extracts this trend in activity and then
identify a “growth cycle” as a deviation from this trend (Stock and Watson, 1999). The
classical methodology we employ, however, is particularly useful for our purpose since we
are interested in business cycles in OECD countries where growth rates have been relatively
low. This implies that growth recessions are small in size and can be frequent, while level
recessions are more pronounced, but fewer (Morsink, Helbling and Tokarick, 2002). The
classical methodology also allows us to focus on a well-defined set of cyclical turning points
12
rather than having to consider how the characterization of business cycles depends on the
specific detrending method used.
7
The turning points identified by our methodology are also
robust to the inclusion of newly available data, whereas new data can affect the estimated
trend and thus the identification of a growth cycle.
The methodology we use determines the peaks and troughs of any given series by first
searching for maxima and minima over a given period of time. It then selects pairs of
adjacent, locally absolute maxima and minima that meet certain censoring rules requiring a
certain minimal duration of cycles and phases. In particular, we employ the algorithm
introduced by Harding and Pagan (2002a), which extends the so called BB algorithm
developed by Bry and Boschan (1971), to identify the cyclical turning points in the log-level
of a series.
8
A complete cycle goes from one peak to the next peak with its two phases, the
contraction phase (from peak to trough) and the expansion phase (from trough to peak). The
algorithm requires that the minimum duration of the complete cycle and each phase must be
at least five and two quarters, respectively.
9
Specifically, a peak is reached in a quarterly
series y
t
at time t if:
-2 -1 2 1
{[( - ) 0, ( - ) 0] [( - ) 0, ( - ) 0]}
tt tt t t t t
yy yy and y y y y
++
>> < <
Similarly, a cyclical trough is reached at time t if:
-2 -1 2 1
{[( - ) < 0, ( - ) < 0] [( - ) > 0, ( - ) > 0]}
tt tt t t t t
yy yy and y y y y
++
We employ this algorithm to identify cycles in a variety of macroeconomic and financial
variables. Our main macroeconomic variable is output (GDP) which provides the broadest
measure of economic activity. Besides output, we also look at cycles in a number of
macroeconomic variables, including consumption and investment. In terms of financial
variables, we are interested in cycles in three variables: credit, house prices and equity prices.
The main characteristics of cyclical phases are their duration and amplitude (Harding and
Pagan, 2002a). Since we are mainly interested in examining contractions, we define these
7
There have been a large number of studies documenting that the features of growth cycles can
depend on the detrending method used (Canova, 1998).
8
The algorithm we employ is called the BBQ algorithm since it is applicable to quarterly data. It is
possible to employ a different algorithm, such as a Markov Switching (MS) model (Hamilton, 1989),
to date the turning points. Harding and Pagan (2002b) compare this method with their BBQ algorithm
and conclude that their algorithm is preferable because the MS model depends on the validity of the
underlying statistical framework (see also Hamilton (2003) on this issue). Also using this
methodology, Artis, Kontolemis, and Osborn (1997), Artis, Marcellino, Proietti (2002), Harding and
Pagan (2002a), Cotis and Coppel (2005), and Hall and McDermott (2007) analyze the main features
of business cycles, including cyclical phases and synchronization.
9
In the case of asset prices, the constraint that the contraction phase last at least two quarters is
ignored if the quarterly decline exceeds 20 percent. This is because asset prices can have much more
intra-quarter variation, making for large differences between peaks and troughs based on end-of-
quarter data and those based on higher frequency data.
13
characteristics for contractions only. The duration of a contraction, D
c
, is the number of
quarters, k, between a peak and the next trough. The amplitude of a contraction, A
c
, measures
the change in y
t
from a peak (y
0
) to the next trough (y
k
), i.e., A
c
= y
k
– y
0
. For output, we also
consider another widely used measure, the cumulative loss. This measure combines
information about the duration and amplitude of a phase to proxy the overall cost of a
cyclical contraction, likely of particular interest to policy makers. The cumulative loss, F
c
,
during a contraction, with duration k, is then defined as:
0
1
()
2
c
k
c
j
j
A
Fyy
=
=−
.
We further classify recessions based on the extent of decline in output. In particular, we call
recessions mild or severe if the peak-to-trough output drop falls into the bottom or top
quartile of all output drops during recessions, respectively. Likewise, declines in asset prices
and credit contractions are distinguished according to their severity. An equity (or house)
price bust is defined as a peak-to-trough decline which falls into the top quartile of all equity
(or house) price declines (Helbling and Terrones, 2003). Similarly, a credit crunch is defined
as a peak-to-trough contraction in credit which falls into the top quartile of all credit
contractions.
10
We identify 122 recessions in output (30 of which are severe), 112
contractions (28 crunches) in credit, 114 declines (28 busts) in house prices, 234 declines (58
busts) in equity prices.
In line with the way we date events in general, we next use a simple “dating” rule regarding
whether or not a specific recession is associated with a credit crunch or asset price bust. In
particular, if a recession episode starts at the same time or after the beginning of an ongoing
credit crunch or asset price bust, we consider the recession to be associated with the
respective credit crunch or asset price bust.
This rule, by definition, basically describes a
“timing” association (or coincidence) between the two events but does not imply a causal
link.
11
Among these events, there is a considerable overlap, since there are 18, 34 and 45 recession
episodes associated with credit crunches, house price busts and equity price busts,
respectively (Figure 1 provides the Venn diagram of the associations of recessions, crunches
and busts).
12
In other words, in about one out of six recessions, there is also a credit crunch
10
We rely on the changes in the volume of (real) credit to identify the episodes of credit crunches,
which is often defined as an excessive decline in the supply of credit that cannot be explained by
cyclical changes (see Bernanke and Lown, 1991). It is difficult to separate the roles played by
demand and supply factors in the determination of credit volume in the economy. An alternative
methodology to identify credit crunch episodes would be to consider an interest rate measure, i.e.,
track changes in the price of credit over time. We plan to explore this in future research.
11
An example of the fact that “association” does not describe causality is when exogenous shocks
cause a recession that otherwise would not have happened even when a credit crunch or asset price
bust was already occurring.
12
Although we have 34 recessions associated with housing busts, we have only 28 episodes of
housing busts. This is since housing busts last much longer than recessions do, and some housing
(continued…)
14
underway and in about one out of four recessions, also a house price bust. Equity price busts
overlap for about one-third of recession episodes.
13
Our algorithm closely replicates the dates of U.S. business cycles as determined by the
NBER Business Cycle Dating Committee. According to the NBER, the United States has
experienced 7 recessions over the 1960-2007 period and our algorithm provides exact
matches for 4 out of these 7 peak and trough dates and is only a quarter early in dating the
remaining peaks and troughs. The differences between our dates and the NBER ones stem
from the fact that the NBER uses monthly data for various activity indicators (including
industrial production, employment, personal income net of transfer payments, and the
volume of sales of the manufacturing and wholesale retail sectors), whereas we solely
employ quarterly series on output to identify the cyclical turning points. Nevertheless, the
main features of business cycles based on the turning points we document are quite similar to
those of the NBER. The average duration of U.S. business cycles based on our turning
points, for example, is the same as that reported by the NBER. In addition, the average
amplitude of cycles derived from our methodology is very close to that of the NBER cycles.
14
III. WHAT HAPPENS DURING RECESSIONS?
In this section, we first examine a set of basic stylized facts about recessions, including their
duration, amplitude, and cumulative output loss, and how these features vary across
countries. We then document the changes in our main macroeconomic and financial variables
during recessions. This is followed by an analysis of the temporal behavior of these same
variables around recessions. Last, we analyze the synchronization of recessions across
countries.
A. Basic Features of Recessions: Duration and Cost
Table 1A presents the main characteristics of recessions for each country in our sample.
Throughout the paper, we most often focus on medians because they are less affected by the
presence of outliers in our sample. Wherever relevant, however, we also refer to means. A
typical OECD country experienced about five recessions over the 1960-2007 period. There is
no apparent pattern across countries in the number of recessions, but some countries do stand
out. For example, Canada, Ireland, Japan, Norway and Sweden witnessed only three
recessions during this period, while Italy and Switzerland had 9 recessions, and New Zealand
busts are associated with multiple recessions. In particular, there are five housing busts that overlap
with two recessions each, and two busts that overlap with three recessions each.
13
Overlaps of recessions with credit contractions and asset price declines are numerous and we
briefly examine the implications of such overlaps in the later sections. The dates of the cyclical
turning points are available upon request.
14
In particular, the average peak-to-trough decline in output during the U.S. recessions is around
-1.7 percent based on our dates while it is -1.4 percent based on the NBER dates. We provide a
detailed discussion of the implications of recessions in the United States in Claessens, Kose and
Terrones (2008).
15
12, the most.
15
A typical recession lasts about 4 quarters (one year) with relatively small
variation across countries—the shortest recession is 2 quarters and the longest 13 quarters.
Roughly one-third of all recessions are short with only 2 quarters. The proportion of time
spent in recession, defined as the fraction of quarters the economy is in recession over the
full sample period, is typically around 10 percent.
16
In addition to duration, we describe the severity of a recession using two other metrics. The
median (average) decline in output from peak to trough, the recession’s amplitude, is about
1.9 (2.7) percent. It ranges from about 1 percent for the typical recession in Austria, Belgium,
Ireland and Spain to more than 6 percent for those in Greece and New Zealand. The
cumulative loss of a typical (median) recession is about 3 percent, but the average loss is
about 6.4 percent since the distribution is skewed to the right (there is on average a small
positive correlation (0.34) between duration and amplitude). This also shows that the overall
loss can differ quite a bit from amplitude as durations vary. Country examples further
illustrate this difference. For example, while the median amplitude of recessions in Finland
and Sweden are not as large as those in Greece and New Zealand, recessions in Finland and
Sweden have very large cumulative output losses (23 and 16 percent, respectively) since their
recessions are long.
As mentioned, a recession is classified as a severe one when the peak-to-trough decline in
output is in the top-quartile of all output declines during recessions, which means a peak-to-
trough output decline below -3.2 percent. While many OECD countries, including Austria,
Belgium, France, Ireland, Norway, Spain, and the United States, did not experience a severe
recession in the sample period, most recessions in Greece and New Zealand fell in this
category. The 30 such recessions we document are typically five quarters long, more than a
quarter longer than the average recession. They are, by construction, much more costly than
other recessions with a median decline of about 5 percent, almost three times that of other
recessions, and have a cumulative loss of about 10 percent, five times that of the other
recessions. An extremely severe recession, in which the peak-to-trough decline in output
exceeds 10 percent, is usually called a depression, of which there are 5 in our sample. The
last such depression episode took place in Finland in the early 1990s with an output decline
of 14 percent.
17
15
New Zealand has the highest number of recessions primarily because of the highly volatile nature
of its output fluctuations and its large exposure to terms-of-trade shocks. Consistent with this, the
number of recessions in other variables of New Zealand, including consumption, investment and
industrial production, also is quite high. The dates of New Zealand’s business cycles we report are
largely consistent with those reported in Morsink, Helbling, and Tokarick (2001) which documents
seven recessions over the 1973-2000 period. Hall and McDermott (2006), using unpublished output
data, identify 9 recessions for New Zealand during the 1946:1-2005:4 period.
16
The proportion of time a country spends in recession relates of course closely to the number of
recessions the country experienced (the correlation between the two is 0.9). The number and average
duration of recessions have, however, a small negative correlation (-0.26) since some countries
experienced many short recessions in relatively brief periods. For example, New Zealand had five
short recessions during the 1970s and Japan witnessed its three recessions after 1992.
17
The 5 depressions that occurred are: New Zealand (1966:4-1967:2); New Zealand (1974:3-1975:2);
New Zealand (1976:4-1978:1); Greece (1973:4-1974:3); and Finland (1990:1-1993:2). While the
(continued…)
16
As shown in Figure 2, most recessions lasted 4 quarters or less, and most of these were also
mild to moderate in depth, i.e., less than a 3.2 percent output decline.
18
Of the severe
recessions in our sample, only 40 percent were long, i.e., lasted more than 5 quarters. There
is also a pattern of recessions becoming shorter and milder over time, especially after the
mid-1980s. In particular, the amplitude of a typical recession fell from 2.6 percent in 1973-
1985 to 1.4 percent in 1986-2007. These patterns are in line with recent empirical work
documenting a trend decline in output volatility in industrial countries, the so called “Great
Moderation” phenomenon.
19
B. Changes in Macroeconomic and Financial Variables
We next examine how the main macroeconomic and financial variables typically vary during
a recession. Table 1B presents the peak-to-trough changes for these variables for all, severe,
and other recessions, which are those not in the group of severe ones. We find the expected
patterns in recessions in the sense that most macroeconomic variables exhibit procyclical
behavior. Not surprisingly, differences between severe and non-severe (other) recessions are
often statistically significant in terms of their durations, amplitudes and cumulative output
losses. In a severe recession, consumption typically drops by more than 1 percent, compared
to almost no change in other recessions. The importance of investment for explaining the
business cycle has been stressed in the literature for a long time. Indeed, both residential and
total investment tend to decline by double digits in severe recessions, compared to a drop of
about 4 percent in other recessions.
Recessions often also overlap with declines in international trade. Exports drop more in
severe recessions compared to other recessions (and significantly so). As expected, imports
fall, by six times more than exports in a typical recession and by close to 10 percent in severe
recessions (statistical significantly more so than in other recessions). While both net exports
and the current account balance register improvements during recessions, the changes are not
statistical significantly different across the types of recessions.
The fall in industrial production tracks closely the drop in investment in all types of
recessions and is larger than that of output. Recessions often coincide with an increase in the
unemployment rate (in 90 percent of cases). The unemployment rate typically rises three
times as much in severe recessions than in other recessions. Inflation typically drops slightly
(in 60 percent of all recessions), as expected given that aggregate demand is often down in
recessions, but inflation does not seem to vary between the types of recessions, possibly as
some severe recessions have been of the stagflation typea recession combined with an
depression in Finland was the longest one with 13 quarters, the deepest one was the one in New
Zealand leading to roughly 15 percent reduction in output over the 1976:4-1978:1 period. See Kehoe
and Prescott (2002) for a discussion of a number of depressions in the 20
th
century.
18
To be more specific, around 35 percent of all recessions are short with 2 quarters, 40 percent are
medium duration of 3-4 quarters, and 25 percent are long with 5 quarters or more.
19
Explanations for this decrease are many, ranging from “the new economy” driven changes to the
use of effective monetary policy during the recent period (see Blanchard and Simon, 2001; and Stock
and Watson, 2003).
17
acceleration in the rate of inflation. We discuss the implications of such recessions later in
the paper.
Next, we examine the changes in our key financial variables during recessions. Although
credit typically continues to grow, it does so only at about 1 percent, with its growth rate
especially low in the initial stages of recessions. Credit growth does not vary much, however,
between severe and other recessions. Both house and equity prices typically contract in
recessions, with larger declines in house prices in severe than in other recessions.
20
Reflecting
the generally more volatile nature of equity prices, the decline in equity prices is more than
twice that of house prices as the median equity price decreases by 16 percent in severe
recessions, or some 12 percent more than in other recessions.
We also study the quarterly changes in the main macroeconomic variables during recessions
and compare them with those during non-recession (expansion) periods. This exercise can be
seen as another way of evaluating the cost of recessions relative to the average growth rate of
the economy during expansionary periods. The median quarterly decline in output during
recessions is around -0.5 percent whereas during expansionary periods it is close to
0.9 percent. This suggests that a typical recession leads to roughly 1.5 percent decline in
output per quarter compared with the periods of expansions the countries normally enjoy.
The average rate of contraction in consumption was much smaller than that in output with
0.03 percent per quarter, but the rate of growth during expansions was close to 0.75 percent.
More volatile variables of national income exhibit sharper differences in growth across the
periods of recessions and expansions.
C. Dynamics of Recessions
We next examine how various macroeconomic, trade and financial variables behave around
recessions (see Figure 3). We focus on patterns in the year-on-year growth in each variable
over a 6-year window—12 quarters before and 12 quarters after a peak.
21
All panels include
the median growth rate, i.e., the typical behavior, along with the top and bottom quartiles. As
noted, according to our definition, the bottom quartile includes the severe recessions, while
the top quartile contains the mild ones.
The evolution of output growth around a recession is as expected. Following the peak at date
0, output tends to register a negative annual growth rate after 3 quarters, and its growth rate
goes down to -1 percent at the end of the fourth quarter after the peak. In severe recessions,
the growth rate falls to -2 percent at that time. Although consumption does not decrease on a
year-to-year basis in a typical recession, it does fall during the first year of a severe recession.
In terms of timing, the evolution of consumption around recessions resembles the behavior of
output.
20
Credit declines during recessions in only around 35 percent of cases while house prices fall in
around 55 percent of all recessions and equity prices register a fall in about 60 percent of them.
21
In our figures, we focus on year-on-year changes in the relevant variables since quarter-to-quarter
changes are often quite volatile and provide a noisy presentation of recession dynamics.
18
Some macroeconomic variables naturally show early signs of a slowdown before the
recession starts. For example, residential investment typically declines sharply ahead of the
onset of recessions. Moreover, both components of investment (residential and non-
residential) often register negative year-to-year changes already in the first quarter of a
recession, i.e., three quarters ahead of output, and their growth rates typically stay negative
for up to 6 quarters implying that the recovery in investment often starts later than that in
output. In severe recessions, recovery of the growth rate of investment can take up to three
years.
Industrial production also shows signs of weakness early on and typically registers a sharp
decline before a recession starts. During the onset of recessions, inflation is typically still on
an increasing path, and unemployment is already starting to rise. After the recession starts,
however, the rate of inflation declines while the increase in the unemployment rate
accelerates. Unemployment is a good leading indicator of economic activity as it typically
begins climbing a quarter ahead of recessions but stays compressed more than a year after the
end of the recession.
In terms of trade variables, the growth rates of both exports and imports slow down in a
recession, but that of imports much more. The growth rate of imports often tends to fall
before the recession starts and can decline to -7 percent in the first year of a severe recession.
While both net exports and the current account balance improve during a typical recession,
the improvement in net exports is often earlier and more pronounced than that of the current
account.
Credit growth also slows down, by some 2 to 3 percentage points before a recession starts,
and then by another 2 percentage points over the recession period, typically not returning to
pre-recession growth rates for at least three years after the recession started. Recessions are
often also proceeded by slowdowns in the growth rates of asset prices. In the first year of a
typical recession, for example, house and equity prices decline on a year-to-year basis by
roughly 3 and 16 percent, respectively. While equity prices often start registering positive
growth after about six quarters, house prices typically decline during the two years after the
end of a recession.
D. Synchronization of Recessions, Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines
We next examine the synchronization of recessions, credit contractions and asset price
declines across countries. Our synchronization measure is simply the fraction of countries
experiencing the same event at the same time.
22
For recessions, Figure 4 shows how this
fraction evolves over time along with the dates of recessions in the United States. The figure
shows recessions bunching in about four periods during 1960–2007. First, a large fraction of
22
Recent research has typically relied on three main measures of synchronization. The first is bilateral
output correlations, which capture co-movements in output fluctuations of two countries. The second
is the share of output variances that can be attributed to synthetic (unobservable) common factors, as
in Kose, Otrok and Prasad (2003). The third one is the concordance statistic (Harding and Pagan,
2002a), which measures the synchronization of turning points.
19
countries went into recession in the mid-1970s, shortly after the first oil price shock. The
fraction of countries in recession also rose during the second oil price shock and the period of
highly synchronized contractionary monetary policies across major industrial economies in
the early 1980s. In the early 1990s, recessions were again highly synchronized around the
world, and in the early 2000s to some degree. In the first three of these four periods, more
than 50 percent of countries in our sample were in a recession at the same time. The peak
episodes of highly synchronized recessions quickly followed each other in some instances, as
shocks spilled from one country to the other. This was, for example, the case in the early
1990s because of the asymmetric shocks hitting countries across major currency areas (see
Morsink, Helbling and Tokarick, 2002).
23
We document in the same way the synchronization of turning points in consumption and
investment. A well known stylized fact of business cycles is that investment is much more
volatile than output and consumption is somewhat less volatile than output (Backus, Kehoe
and Kydland, 1995).
24
In our sample, indeed, investment declines in three-fourth of all
recessions while consumption contracts in only half of all recessions. Consistent with these
observations, the fraction of countries experiencing a period of investment (consumption)
contraction at any time is much higher (lower) than that of those experiencing recessions.
And, while investment contractions are highly synchronized, consumption contractions are
much less so. These results are consistent with recent findings suggesting that common
factors play a much larger role in explaining fluctuations in investment than they do in
consumption (Kose, Otrok and Prasad, 2008).
25
Recessions tend to coincide with contractions in domestic credit and declines in asset prices,
as documented in Section IIIC. This also shows up in the fraction of countries experiencing
recessions around the world being highly correlated with the fractions of those going through
credit contractions or bear asset markets (Figure 5). In particular, credit contractions are
closely associated with recessions. House price declines are also highly synchronized across
countries,
despite the fact that housing is a nontradable asset, and the degree of
synchronization rises especially during recession episodes.
26
Equity prices exhibit the highest
degree of synchronization reflecting the extensive integration of financial markets. However,
23
Kose, Otrok and Whiteman (2008) examine the degree of synchronization of G-7 business cycles
using a dynamic factor model. They report that a common factor, on average, explains a larger share
of the business cycle variation in G-7 countries since the mid-1980s compared to 1960–1972.
24
For a detailed analysis of the volatility and comovement properties of business cycles for a large set
of countries, see Kose, Prasad and Terrones (2003a, 2003b).
25
We also analyze the synchronization of turning points in industrial production, exports and imports.
As expected, the proportion of countries experiencing a contraction in industrial production is very
closely correlated with that going through a recessionary period. The results indicate that
synchronized recessions across countries have particularly adverse effects on global trade flows as
evidenced by the higher fraction of countries experiencing contractions in their exports and imports
than those witnessing recessions. We also examine the fraction of countries experiencing both real
and financial cycles at the same time, such as recessions, credit contractions and/or asset price
declines. The results of these additional exercises are consistent with the findings we report here.
26
Terrones (2004) shows that house prices tend to move together across countries and they are
procyclical, rising in economic expansions and falling in recessions.
20
the popular saying that “Wall Street has predicted nine of the last five recessions” resonates
here as the fraction of countries experiencing bear equity markets frequently exceeds the
fraction of countries in a recession.
IV. WHAT HAPPENS DURING CREDIT CONTRACTIONS AND ASSET PRICE DECLINES?
In this section, we study the main features of the episodes of credit contractions and declines
in the prices of housing and equity in our sample. As we explained in Section II, credit
contractions and asset price declines that fall into the top quartile of all credit contractions
and asset price declines are classified as credit crunches and asset price busts, respectively. In
particular, when the peak-to-trough decline in credit exceeds 9.5 percent, it is called a crunch
episode, and when the decline in house (equity) price is larger than 14.3 (38.7) percent, it
qualifies as a house (equity) price bust. In the following sub-sections, we first document the
basic stylized facts of each of these credit contraction/crunch and asset price decline/bust
events and then examine the temporal patterns of various macroeconomic and financial
variables around these episodes.
A. Episodes of Credit Contractions
Table 2A shows the main features of credit contractions and crunches for each country in our
sample. There are 112 (28) credit contraction (crunch) episodes. A typical OECD country
went through about 6 credit contractions, but there is much variation across countries.
Germany, the Netherlands, and Spain witnessed only a few contractions (2 to 3) while
Greece, New Zealand and Portugal had the highest number (8). Austria, France, Germany
and Switzerland never experienced a credit crunch episode during the 1960-2007 period, but
the other countries in our sample had at least one.
The median (average) credit contraction episode lasts 4 (6) quarters. Credit crunches last
typically twice as long, 8 quarters, and are statistically significantly longer than non-crunch
(other) contraction episodes (Table 2B). Credit contractions usually mean some 4 percent
decline in credit from peak to trough. In case of crunches, the decline in credit is 17 percent,
significantly more than during the non-crunch episodes.
While output growth slows down, especially early on in a credit contraction or crunch
episode (as we show next), output typically is higher at the end than at the beginning of these
episodes. The increase in output during contractions and crunches is not surprising since
these episodes do not always fully overlap with recessions and last twice as long as
recessions do. Output also expands significantly more during crunches than during other
contractions, probably because the duration of a typical crunch episode is 5 quarters longer
than the duration of a typical non-crunch episode. Still, the average growth rate of output in
credit crunch episodes is less than half of that observed during other periods.
27
27
In particular, the quarterly growth rate of output is typically around 0.3 percent when there is a
credit crunch whereas it is more than 0.8 percent during other contraction episodes.
21
Credit contractions are associated with visibly strong negative effects on investment. In
particular, credit contractions (crunches) are typically accompanied with declines in
residential investment of about 1 (6) percent over the period when credit contracts. The
unemployment rate is typically flat during a credit contraction, but increases significantly
during a credit crunch episode, primarily because of job losses early on in these episodes
when economic activity also weakens.
With respect to other financial variables, house prices typically decline significantly more
during credit crunches, by some 10 percent versus 1 percent in the typical non-crunch
episode. While equity prices usually also decline somewhat during credit contractions, they
actually increase over the credit crunch episodes, perhaps anticipating a recovery from the
deeper credit slump and the longer duration of these episodes.
We then examine how the various macroeconomic and financial variables behave around
credit crunches (Figure 6). As for recessions, we focus on patterns in the year-on-year growth
in each variable over a 6-year window—12 quarters before and 12 quarters after a peak of
credit expansion. All panels include the median growth rates, i.e., the typical behavior, along
with the top and bottom quartiles. As before, the bottom quartile denotes the worst 25 percent
of all credit crunches and the top quartile the best 25 percent.
Output growth typically starts declining two quarters before the beginning of a credit crunch
and goes down by 2 percentage points after the fifth quarter. Although output growth
typically does not become negative on a year-to-year basis in a credit crunch, it does so in at
least one-quarter of the crunch episodes as evidenced by the bottom quartile. In a typical
credit crunch, the year-on-year growth rate in consumption goes down as well and can fall to
-2 percent in about five quarters in some crunch episodes.
As expected, investment weakens before the credit crunch starts. In particular, residential
investment typically starts to slow down much before the crunch episode begins, and actually
shrinks one quarter ahead of the start of the episode. Growth rates of total investment and
residential investment typically stay negative for up to 8 quarters. Moreover, investment can
take up to three years and residential investment even longer to recover in some episodes of
credit crunches, much longer than the duration of slowdown in output. Inflation is on an
increasing path and unemployment is already starting to rise prior to the start of a credit
crunch, but as activity slows down after the beginning of a crunch, the rate of inflation
declines and the increase in the rate of unemployment accelerates.
Credit crunches are generally preceded by a period of rapid expansion in credit, but are most
often accompanied by slowdowns in asset prices. The median (year-to-year) credit growth is
5 to 6 percent just before the peak of credit expansion is reached and then slows down
sharply over the crunch period, by more than 10 percentage points, falling to -6 percent and
not returning to positive levels until 10 quarters after the credit crunch started. The rapid
decline in credit during this period likely reflects both lower demand, e.g., decrease in
investment, but also a fall in supply due to bank capital shortfalls and other adverse supply
side effects. The figure shows the clear spillover effects from tight credit markets to the
housing and equity markets. In particular, house prices typically fall in the first year of a
22
credit crunch and continue to decline for at least three years after the beginning of a crunch
episode. Equity prices often decline before a credit crunch episode starts and further weaken
during the first year, but then frequently stage a recovery ahead of the pick up in credit.
B. Episodes of Declines in House Prices
Table 3A shows the main features of house price declines and busts for each country in our
sample. There are 114 (28) episodes of house price decline (bust) implying that a typical
country experienced around 6 such episodes. Australia and Canada had the largest number
(9) of decline episodes while Greece had only 1. While the majority of countries had at least
one house price bust over the 1960-2007 period, Australia, Belgium, Germany, Greece,
Portugal, the United Kingdom, and the United States did not experience any.
28
The typical
episode of a decline in house prices lasts 6 quarters, but housing busts usually last more than
16 quarters. While the typical (median) decline in house prices is only 6 percent, due to some
very large declines in the sample, the average decline is around 11 percent. During a house
price bust, prices decline by about 29 percent typically.
Like credit contractions, output typically still expands during episodes of house price
declines (Table 3B). As in the case of credit contractions, this mainly reflects that house price
declines last a long time during which output still grows, albeit at a much lower rate.
29
There
appears to be, however, a substantially adverse impact of house price declines on investment
(and its components) which is much larger than that in credit contractions. During periods of
house price declines (busts), residential investment typically shrinks by 4 (12) percent. Total
investment also goes down, typically, by more than 8 percent. While the unemployment rate
usually records a statistically significant increase during bust episodes relative to non-bust
(other decline) episodes, inflation tends to be much lower at the end of house price busts, by
some 3 percentage points. Credit still expands over the episodes of house price declines, but
at a slower rate than normal, and equity prices do not change much. These findings suggest
that developments in the housing market can have particularly strong links with the overall
economy.
Figure 7 presents the dynamics of the key macroeconomic and financial variables around the
periods of house price busts. Although the typical slowdown in output around a house price
bust is more gradual than that in a credit crunch, the dynamics of house price busts are
otherwise quite similar to those of credit crunches. The slowdown in output starts at the time
of the house price bust and is associated with a slowdown in consumption growth.
Investment declines largely occur after the onset of the house price decline and involve
contractions in both residential and nonresidential investment. While residential investment
declines less sharply after the first year of the beginning of a house price bust than that of a
credit crunch, the recovery of residential investment takes much longer in house price busts.
28
Since our study focuses on the completed events only, current declines in house prices in the United
States and some other advanced countries are not included in these calculations.
29
For example, the quarterly growth rate of output during house price busts is typically about one-
fourth of that in periods without busts.
23
After a few quarters, and often following a run-up, inflation typically experiences a sharp
decline, and unemployment starts to rise after about two years as the impact of the house
price decline is gradually felt more broadly. As noted, house prices remain on the decline for
long periods during a bust episode, typically much more than three years. While equity prices
start falling before the onset, they usually begin to recover within two years of a house price
bust. Credit growth experiences a large slowdown and does not return to the pre-bust levels
for at least three years.
C. Episodes of Declines in Equity Prices
Table 4A presents the main features of equity price declines and busts for each country in our
sample. Since equity prices are much more volatile than house prices, there are many more
episodes, 234 (58), of declines (busts) in equity than in house prices. In a typical country,
there were around 11 (3) episodes of equity declines (busts). While Italy had 7 equity bust
episodes, Greece, Spain and the United States experienced only one. Episodes of declines
vary quite a bit in terms of their durations and amplitudes across countries, but they typically
last 5 quarters and are associated with a price drop of 27 percent. Equity busts, however,
typically last 10 quarters and are accompanied with a 50 percent price decline.
As in the cases of credit contractions and house price declines, while both output and
consumption also continue to grow during episodes of equity price declines, they do so at
lower rates than typical (Table 4B).
30
However, different than for credit contractions and
house price declines, there is no decline in investment over the episodes of equity price
declines. While unemployment picks up a little bit, the rate of inflation does not change
much during periods of equity price declines. Credit still registers an expansion and house
prices typically increase between the peak and trough of the equity price decline episodes. In
sum, equity price declines appear somewhat less related to the real economy than credit
contractions or house prices declines.
The weak connection between the dynamics of equity prices and economic activity is also
reflected in the behavior of the main macroeconomic variables (Figure 8). The growth rate of
output slows down, but this usually starts only three quarters after the beginning of the equity
bust and is much more limited, with the level of output typically not experiencing a decline.
The extent of slowdown in consumption growth associated with an equity price bust is also
delayed—until after one year or so, and is weaker than that observed during credit crunches
and house price busts. The decline in investment growth follows with a relatively long lag the
start of the equity price bust—only after 3 to 4 quarters does investment growth slow down.
The growth rate of non-residential investment increases for a few quarters after the start of
the bust, before falling at a much faster rate than residential investment growth. Inflation
30
The median quarterly growth rate of output during equity busts is typically around 0.5 percent
while it is about 0.8 percent during the periods without such busts. Other variables, including
consumption, investment and its components, also register weaker growth during the episodes of
equity busts relative to other periods.
24
typically remains elevated and unemployment experiences only a very small increase after an
equity price bust.
The fall in equity prices itself is a sharp and prolonged one as prices do not start to recover
within the three year period following the start of the bust. Credit growth experiences a
delayed slowdown as well, only to pick up somewhat two years after the beginning of the
equity bust. Interestingly, there appears to be also a lag in terms of the behavior of house
prices, since their growth rate typically starts to decline only after one year, becoming
negative after two years.
These findings suggest that the temporal dynamics of the main components of domestic
absorption after credit crunches and house price busts resemble the behavior they exhibit
during recessions. For example, the much larger decline in the growth rate of investment
compared with that of consumption is a feature of recessions as well, as documented in the
previous section. The sharper fall in consumption following house price busts than that
following equity price busts is consistent with the result that recessions associated with house
price busts are generally more costly than those associated with equity price busts, as we are
about to document in the next section.
D. Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines: A Summary
Table 5 summarizes the implications of the episodes of credit contractions, house prices
declines and equity price declines. In terms of duration, the episodes of declines and busts of
house prices last longer than credit contractions/crunches or equity price declines/busts.
While less persistent than house price declines, drops in equity prices are much larger. In
particular, a typical episode of house price decline (bust) leads to a 6 (29) percent drop in
house prices, while an episode of equity price decline (bust) tends to result in a 27 (50)
percent fall in equity prices. Both credit crunches and house price busts have adverse effects
on the growth rate of investment, its components, and unemployment. House price busts, in
particular, are associated with larger drops in investment and the rate of employment.
Residential investment, for example, declines by 6 and 12 percent during credit crunches and
house busts, respectively.
V. WHAT HAPPENS DURING RECESSIONS ASSOCIATED WITH CRUNCHES AND BUSTS?
We now analyze the features of recessions that are associated with credit crunches, house
price busts and equity price busts. As we explained in section II, if a recession episode starts
at the same time or after the beginning of an ongoing credit crunch or asset price bust, we
consider that recession to be associated with the respective credit crunch or asset price bust.
We identified 18, 34 and 45 recession episodes associated with credit crunches, house price
busts and equity price busts, respectively. The association we focus on, by definition, implies
a coincidence between the two events, but does not suggest a causal link. To provide a sense
of distributions, we also examine the features of recessions coinciding with severe credit
crunches or asset price busts. These severe crunch/bust episodes consist of the top 12.5
percent of all credit contractions or asset price declines (or the top half of all credit crunches
or asset price busts).
25
A. Recessions Associated with Credit Crunches
We first examine the number of lags between the start of a credit crunch and the beginning of
the corresponding recession. If a recession is associated with a credit crunch, it typically
starts 4-5 quarters after the onset of the credit crunch (Table 6). Since credit crunches last
longer than do recessions, the latter tend to end 2 quarters before their corresponding credit
crunch episodes. These findings suggest that the phenomenon of “creditless recoveries” is
not specific to sudden stop episodes observed in emerging markets (see Calvo, Izquierdo and
Talvi, 2006) but is also a feature of business cycles in industrial countries.
Table 7 presents the main features of recessions associated with or without credit crunches.
The average duration of a recession associated with a (severe) credit crunch slightly exceeds
that without a crunch, but the difference is not statistically significant. Interestingly,
recessions ended before their corresponding credit crunch episodes completed in all except
four cases. There is typically a larger output decline in those recessions associated with a
credit crunch compared to other recessions, -2.2 versus -1.8 percent, or a 0.4 percentage
points difference (although this is again not statistically significant). For recessions with a
severe credit crunch though, the difference in output decline is larger, 0.9 percentage points,
and statistically significant.
The cumulative output loss of recessions associated with (severe) crunches is typically
significantly larger than those without crunches. In particular, the average (median)
cumulative loss of a recession associated with a severe crunch is two times that of without a
crunch. Recessions with crunches are generally associated with greater contractions in
consumption, investment, industrial production, employment, exports and imports, compared
to those recessions without crunches. Except for industrial production, however, these
differences are not significant.
Credit, by construction, registers much larger (and statistically significant) declines in
recessions with crunches than those without crunches (Dell’ Ariccia and Garibaldi, 2005).
House prices also fall statistically significantly more in recessions with crunches than those
without. This might stem from the high sensitivity of housing activity to credit conditions
(Kiyotaki and Moore, 1997; Mendoza and Terrones, 2008). In contrast, equity prices actually
decrease less in recessions with crunches and even record increases in recessions with severe
crunches. This may reflect that equity prices decline more in the onset of recessions and that
markets anticipate a recovery during these types of recessions.
B. Recessions Associated with House Price Busts
There are a number of statistically significant differences between recessions coinciding with
house price busts and those without busts (Table 8). In particular, recessions associated with
house price busts are on average over a quarter longer than those without busts. Moreover,
output declines (and corresponding cumulative losses) are typically much larger in recessions
with busts, 2.2 (3.7) percent versus 1.5 (2.3) percent in those without busts. These sizeable
differences also extend to the other macroeconomic variables, including consumption,
investment and the unemployment rate. For example, although consumption typically does
26
not decrease much in recessions (as documented in Section III.A), there is a statistically
significant decline in consumption in recessions associated with house price busts and in case
of severe busts a more than 1 percentage points decline. The large fall likely reflects the
substantial effects of housing wealth on consumption.
31
These findings collectively suggest
that recessions with house price bust have the potential to result in more adverse
macroeconomic outcomes than do those without such busts.
In terms of trade variables, there are also substantial differences between the recessions
coinciding with house price busts and other types of recessions. In part reflecting the
substantial decline in domestic demand, and thus imports, along with an increase in exports,
both the net exports and the current account balance improve significantly more in recessions
with house price busts.
With respect to financial outcomes, by construction, house prices fall much more in
recessions with housing busts (by some 6 percentage points more), but credit also contracts
more, with both differences statistically significant. Equity prices also decline during all
types of recessions, but less so during recessions with housing busts—again, as markets may
already be pricing in a recovery (these differences are, however, not statistically significant).
These comparisons collectively suggest that the more adverse effects of a recession with a
(severe) house price bust arise in part due to compressed credit markets, in turn leading to a
considerable reduction in consumption and (residential) investment.
32
Similar to those associated with credit crunches, recessions associated with house price busts
tend to begin 3-4 quarters after the start of their respective house price busts. However, they
also end 9 quarters ahead of the corresponding house price busts because house price busts
typically last three times longer than recessions (see Table 6). Moreover, when a recession is
associated with a house price bust, residential investment stays depressed for a prolonged
period of time and typically recovers only 3 to 5 quarters after the end of that recession.
C. Recessions Associated with Equity Price Busts
Although recessions associated with equity price busts tend to be longer and deeper than
those without equity busts, these differences are not statistically significant (Table 9). This
might reflect that equity price busts have a less tight relationship with developments in the
real economy compared to credit crunches and house price busts. Nevertheless,
nonresidential and total investment, and industrial production fall significantly more in
recessions with equity price busts vis-à-vis recessions without equity busts. Imports also
31
Housing wealth is often found to have a larger effect on consumption than financial assets wealth
does. Carrol, Otsuka and Slacalek (2006) report that the propensity to consume from a $1 increase in
housing wealth ranges between 2 (short-run) and 9 (long-run) cents, twice as large as that estimated
for equity wealth.
32
There is a large literature suggesting that housing market developments play an important role in
driving business cycles (see Leamer, 2007; and Muellbauer, 2007).
27
decline significantly more and net exports improve much more in recessions with equity
price busts.
With respect to financial variables, differences are, by construction, pronounced for equity
prices, typically a 12 percentage points greater drop in equity price bust recessions. There is
also a pattern of house prices declining 3 percent more in recessions with severe equity price
busts. Overall, these comparisons confirm that, while in normal times declines in equity
prices are not necessarily associated with large changes in output, when they take place at the
same time as recessions, such declines tend to coincide with relatively larger movements in
both real and financial variables.
After the onset of an equity price bust, it takes around 5 quarters before the corresponding
recession begins (see Table 6). The duration of a typical equity price bust is two times longer
than that of a recession, but a recession tends to end at the same with its corresponding equity
bust.
D. Recessions Associated with Crunches and Busts: A Summary
When associated with a credit crunch or asset price bust, which type of recession is the most
painful? To facilitate such a comparison, Table 10 provides the duration, amplitude and
cumulative loss for each type of recession. The answer depends in part on the metric used to
measure the cost of recessions. If we use amplitude as the relevant metric, then recessions
associated with credit crunches appear to be as costly as recessions with house price busts,
and both are slightly more costly than recessions with equity price busts. However, if the
cumulative loss measure is the relevant metric, then the recessions associated with credit
crunches are slightly more painful than those with house price busts. Recessions with equity
price busts are the least costly ones on this metric as well.
We also study the implications of recessions that are accompanied by combinations of a
credit crunch and an asset (house or equity price) bust at the same time. Although the number
of observations for such cases is often small, a recession associated with both a crunch and a
bust often leads to a larger cumulative output loss than that with only a crunch or a bust.
33
For
example, the median cumulative loss of 13 recessions associated with both a credit crunch
and a house price bust is -6.7 percent. And the average duration of these episodes is slightly
longer, at more than 5 quarters.
34
33
There are five recessions associated with both a credit crunch and an equity price bust. Seven
recessions are accompanied with a credit crunch and a house price bust at the same time. There are
only four
recessions in our sample that are accompanied by a trilogy of a credit crunch, a house price,
and an equity price bust. While these cases are also associated with larger cumulative output losses,
we can not claim that they are statistically significantly different than the others we examined.
34
We also examine the implications of recessions associated with different combinations of a credit
contraction/crunch and an asset price decline/bust episodes. The results of these additional exercises
are similar to those we report in the paper, in the sense that recessions associated with financial
market difficulties are generally more severe than those without such problems.
28
VI. RECESSIONS ASSOCIATED WITH INCREASES IN OIL PRICES
A large number of recessions in advanced countries have been preceded by sharp increases in
oil prices. In the United States, for example, nine out of ten “modern” recessions started in
the aftermath of an oil price shock (Hamilton, 2005). These observations have led to a
voluminous literature studying the implications of sharp fluctuations in oil prices for the
behavior of various macroeconomic variables over the business cycle (Kilian, 2008).
35
In
theory, the links between oil price and economic fluctuations arise for a variety of reasons.
For example, through their impact on consumption and investment, oil price shocks affect on
output. Some also argue that recessions that followed an oil price shock are primarily due to
contractionary monetary policies employed to curb inflationary effects (Bernanke, Gertler,
and Watson, 1997).
We therefore briefly analyze how the outcomes of a recession vary depending on whether it
coincides with a large increase in the price of oil. As in earlier sections, we simply examine
how various macroeconomic and financial variables behave during recessions associated
with increases in oil prices. Towards this objective, using our standard demarcation of event
spaces, we call an oil price increase an oil price “shock” (severe oil price shock) if the
increase in oil price is in the top quartile (12.5 percent) of all price increases. With this
definition, we find that almost half of the recessions in our sample are associated with an oil
price shock.
Differences between recessions that coincide with oil price shocks and those without appear
to be significant for several key macroeconomic variables (Table 11). The output drop, for
example, is significantly larger for those recessions associated with a severe oil price shock,
2.6 percent versus 1.8 percent for those recessions without an oil price increase. Likewise,
consumption, residential investment and industrial production all register noticeably greater
declines during recessions associated with oil price shocks. Both imports and exports fall
significantly during these types of recessions, but the changes in equity and house prices are
not much different than those of recessions without jumps in oil prices. While the rate of
inflation falls in a typical recession, recessions coinciding with oil price shocks are
accompanied by significantly higher inflation rates, suggesting these are mainly recessions of
the stagflationary type.
Inflation was usually high, and in some cases even accelerating, during most of the
recessions associated with oil price shocks.
36
We also study the recession outcomes
35
Blanchard and Gali (2007) analyze how the relationship between oil price shocks and
macroeconomy has evolved since the 1970s. Crucini, Kose and Otrok (2008) report that the
correlation of the common G-7 business cycle and the relative price of oil has gradually shifted from
negative to positive since 1960. Claessens, Kose and Terrones (2008) provide a review of the role
played by various factors, including abrupt changes in oil prices, driving recessions in the United
States.
36
In particular, we examine the changes in the rate of inflation during the recession periods and
categorize those that fall in the top quartile of all changes as inflation “shocks”. In over one third of
(continued…)
29
associated with spikes in inflation to check whether there are large differences between
stagflationary recessions—recessionary periods accompanied by a pick up in the inflation
rate—and other recessions. The results indicate that these stagflationary recessions are quite
similar to those of recessions with oil price shocks as they also witness a significantly larger
decline in output and, by construction, a much larger jump in the rate of inflation compared
to other recessions. While equity prices fall significantly more in recessions with an
acceleration in inflation, the changes in other financial variables are not statistically
significantly different from other recessions.
VII. POLICY RESPONSES DURING RECESSIONS, CRUNCHES AND BUSTS
There are many ways in which policy makers can respond to a recession, credit crunch or
asset price bust, including, besides monetary and fiscal policies, interventions in the financial
and corporate sectors, quasi-fiscal operations, changes in exchange rate management
practices, structural reforms etc. To keep matters manageable, and for the sake of
comparability across the diverse set of countries and events under consideration, this section
briefly discusses only two narrow aspects of policy responses: monetary policies, proxied by
changes in (short-term) interest rates, and fiscal policies, captured by changes in government
consumption. Although we are well aware of the problems in associating these variables to
the rather broad concepts of fiscal and monetary policies, we do think that this exercise can
be useful to see general patterns across different types of recessions.
37
Table 12 reports the medians of peak-to-trough changes in short-term nominal and real rates
and real government consumption for the nine different sets of events (combinations) we
have studied in the previous sections. Policy responses vary across events under
consideration as well as depending on the severity of these events. Both monetary and fiscal
policies tend to be countercyclical during recessions, credit contractions and asset price
declines. Moreover, fiscal policy appears to be more accommodative when the episodes are
severe recessions, credit crunches and asset price busts.
38
In episodes involving credit crunches, house price and equity price busts, government
consumption rises significantly more than in other contraction and bust episodes. This
suggests a more aggressive countercyclical fiscal policy at work in recessions with credit
crunches, possibly because monetary policy can be less effective in these circumstances.
During house price busts, the decline in nominal interest rates is also statistically
significantly larger than those episodes without house price busts. However, other differences
are not statistically significant. For example, while government consumption increases more
recessions in our sample, there is an increase in the rate of inflation. The results about recessions
associated with inflation shocks are available upon request.
37
Romer and Romer (1994) argue that monetary policy plays a particularly important role to end
recessions in the United States while fiscal policy appears to have only a limited impact. Perry and
Schultze (1992) also consider the roles played by various policies during the U.S. recessions.
38
Morsink, Helbling, and Tokarick (2002) report that the extent of declines in interest rates during
recessions does not change much across decades and does not appear to be influenced by either the
amplitude of recession or the peak level of interest rate during recession.
30
in severe recessions than it does in other recessions, the difference is not statistically
significant.
With respect to recessionary episodes coinciding with crunches and busts, while most of the
changes in policy responses across recessions associated with different types of financial
market difficulties are intuitively appealing, they are not statistically significant. The only
significant difference is for government consumption during recessions with credit crunches
since its growth rate increases to twice that in recessions without crunches.
We also examine whether policy responses differ depending on whether recessions overlap
with oil price shocks or with large increases in inflation. We find that the drops in short-term
real interest rates are larger in recessions with oil price shocks as well as in those with a jump
in inflation, with differences statistically significant. At the same time, the nominal short-
term interest rate stays constant in the case of recessions with a large increase in inflation,
while decreasing in other recessions; this difference is also statistically significant. This
opposite pattern of real interest rate declines and a constant nominal interest rate reflects that
during these episodes of stagflationary recessions, nominal interest rate increases did not
keep up with inflation increases.
VIII. RECESSION OUTCOMES AND FINANCIAL FACTORS
In previous sections, we examined how recessions associated with credit crunches and asset
price busts are different from those without such financial market difficulties. We now turn
to a preliminary analysis of the empirical links between output losses and changes in
financial market conditions during these episodes. In particular, we employ basic regression
models to examine how the amplitude of a recession is associated with changes in financial
variables during recessions, considering at the same time the fiscal and monetary policies in
place, and domestic and global economic conditions. This exercise deepens our analysis of
the earlier sections as it provides some insights about the roles played by various financial
factors influencing the severity of recessions, while at the same considering other variables.
What are the determinants of the costs of recessions? A number of distinct factors can of
course affect the recession outcomes, but we focus on a small set of variables in our
regressions based on the findings in the previous sections and earlier literature.
39
Our analysis
in the previous sections suggests that changes in financial variables are important in
39
Our objective here is not to analyze the sources of business cycles, but is simply to correlate some
financial factors to the cost of recessions. The sources of business cycles have traditionally been a
topic of intense discussion (see, for instance, Zarnowitz (1985, 1998); Blanchard, 1993;Blanchard and
Watson, 1984; Cochrane, 1994; Stock and Watson, 1999; and Romer, 1999). While some economists
argue that cycles are originated by changes in demand or supply conditions, others emphasize the
importance of shocks stemming from economic policies. Some others claim that the main sources of
business cycles are productivity shocks (Kydland and Edward, 1982; Plosser, 1989). In recent work,
Crucini, Kose and Otrok (2008) examine the roles played by various shocks, including to
productivity, fiscal policy, monetary policy, terms of trade and oil, in explaining international
business cycles.
31
determining recession outcomes as recessions associated with credit crunches and house
prices busts are more costly than those without such episodes. In order to examine their roles,
we include therefore as regressors the changes in credit, housing and equity prices during
recessions.
In addition to these financial variables, we analyze how general economic conditions
prevailing at the onset of recessions are associated with recession outcomes. As a simple
proxy for the state of the domestic economy, we use the cumulative growth of output over
the two years preceding the recession. This variable allows us to examine whether the
strength of the expansionary phase of the cycle plays any role in determining the depth of the
ensuing recession. We also control for global economic conditions with a variable capturing
the strength of external demand. In particular, we include in the regressions the change in
exports during recessions since global demand can be a buffer to downturns in domestic
demand in open economies. Since fluctuations in oil prices also appear to be associated with
different recession outcomes, we include as an additional regressor the growth rate of oil
prices in the two years preceding the recession.
Fiscal and monetary policies are often employed to mitigate the cost of recessions. While
several observers argue that these policies can help moderate recessions, some others claim
that they can worsen recession outcomes. To examine the roles of fiscal and monetary
policies in determining the cost of recessions, we simply include in our regressions the
changes in government expenditures and short-term real interest rates during recessions. Of
course, these variables also respond to recessions themselves, and as such our regressions
pick up associations, not necessarily causalities.
As reported earlier, there is evidence that recessions have become milder over time,
especially since the mid-1980s, an observation coined the “Great Moderation” in the
volatility of business cycles. We therefore include a “Great Moderation” dummy (which
takes the value of one after 1986:2, and zero otherwise) to take into account the changes in
the amplitude of recessions over time. We also control for the adverse effects of financial
crises by including a crisis dummy (which takes the value of one if the country experiences a
banking crisis, a currency crisis, or both crises during a recession or in the year prior to a
recession; and zero otherwise) to determine whether recessions associated with such crises
lead to different outcomes.
We then regress the amplitude of recessions on these financial variables, initial conditions,
and other controls, using a large sample of recessions over the period 1960:1-2007:4. Table
13A reports the results of our baseline OLS regressions. Each of the financial variables enters
into the regressions separately in the first three columns. The coefficients on financial
variables are positive implying that the extent of the decline in credit, house prices and equity
prices are positively associated with the depth of recessions, with house and equity prices
statistically significant. Perhaps more importantly, a decline in housing prices appears to be
more influential in determining the cost of recessions than does a contraction in credit or a
drop in equity prices.
32
In the fourth column, the role played by house prices is considered along with credit, and the
fifth column reports the results when all financial variables are included in the regression.
The coefficient on housing prices remains statistically significant and positive while the
coefficient on equity prices loses its significance, and the coefficient on credit is now
significant, but its sign changes.
40
The sixth column augments this regression by adding the
duration of recessions. Changes in house prices once again have a significantly positive
influence on the cost of recessions, but the other financial variables do not. These results
collectively suggest that the findings for the changes in house prices are robust and do not
reflect the effects of other financial variables.
Why do changes in house prices appear to be so important in determining the cost of
recessions? Some insights on this question can be gained through mechanically examining
changes in the main components of output during recessions associated with credit crunches
and house price busts. In the earlier sections, we reported that consumption and investment
usually register much sharper declines leading to more pronounced drops in employment
during recessions coinciding with house price busts than during those recessions coinciding
with credit crunches. In particular, the decline in consumption during recessions associated
with house price busts is larger, likely reflecting the effects of the substantial loss of housing
wealth on households.
In addition to the changes in house prices, some other factors also appear to influence the
cost of recessions. For example, the state of the economy is positively associated with the
extent of declines in output during recessions. This is an intuitively appealing result as it
suggests that the higher the growth during the expansionary phase of the cycle, the larger the
contraction during the recessionary phase. Reflecting the synchronous nature of recessions
across countries, the decline in exports is positively correlated with the depth of recessions,
and this finding is significant in almost all specifications.
The period of Great Moderation witnesses indeed milder recessions in most specifications.
41
Neither the change in oil prices nor the presence of a financial crisis appear to affect in a
statistically significant way the severity of recessions. One interpretation of the latter result is
that the changes in financial variables already capture the effect of financial crises on the cost
of recessions, but as we discuss below this may not be a robust explanation as the result
changes in some specifications.
42
As one would expect, the amplitude of a recession is
positively associated with its duration.
40
One possible explanation why credit does not appear to be a robust determinant of the cost of
recessions could be that the volume of credit starts declining after banks tighten their lending
standards. Credit standards (more than the volume of credit) are negatively correlated with economic
activity (Lown and Morgan, 2006).
41
Hall (2008) documents that the “Great Moderation” mainly applies to the volatility of total output,
but, in terms of employment, there is no difference between modern and earlier recessions.
42
We also examine whether (or not) the simultaneous occurrence of a currency or banking crises
makes a difference as to the nature of recessions in our event study. Our preliminary results indicate
that while there are some expected differences, e.g., the length of a recession when there is also a
banking or currency crisis is typically longer, very few of these differences are statistically
(continued…)
33
In summary, across the different specifications we employ, the change in house prices tends
to be the most robust financial variable associated with the depth of recessions.
43
Among the
control variables we use, the state of the economy at the onset of the recession and the
duration of the recession tend to influence most consistently the extent of the decline in
output during recessions. The results also indicate that recessions that take place during the
period of Great Moderation are indeed associated with milder contractions in real activity.
We next study the roles played by fiscal and monetary policies during recessions. As already
discussed in earlier sections, the policy options we consider reflect only two narrow aspects
of policy choices available during recessions. Moreover, there are various problems in
associating our policy measures to the rather broad concepts of fiscal and monetary policies.
However, our simple objective here is to examine whether the inclusion of these factors
changes the results of our baseline regressions, rather than making general statements about
the potency of policies in mitigating the cost of recessions.
The regression results (Table 13B) suggest that, while the measures of fiscal and monetary
policies we consider do not appear to have a significant impact on the depth of recessions,
the inclusion of these factors does not change our main results either. While the no impact
findings with respect to policies seem to be surprising at first sight, they could be rationalized
on multiple grounds. First, as explained above, the measures we consider are rather coarse
proxies of fiscal and monetary policies. Second, it is known that macroeconomic policies
tend to have an effect on output with a lag. Moreover, while fiscal and monetary policies
have often been countercyclical in advanced countries, there have been instances in which
procyclical monetary policies were in place to combat inflation.
We next examine whether these findings are driven by outliers in our sample.
44
Tables 14A-
14B report the results of quantile regressions. Reassuringly, our main findings are preserved.
In particular, the changes in housing prices remain significantly positively correlated with the
costs of recessions. Our findings with respect to the other controls are also consistent with the
ones reported earlier; however, the coefficient on the crisis dummy becomes positive and
statistically significant in one specification, suggesting the that there is a positive association
between the presence of financial crises and the cost of recessions. This result echoes the
significant. One notable statistically significant difference, however, is that residential investment
falls more during recessions that overlap with banking crises. Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) and
Cardarelli, Elekdag and Lall (2008) examine macroeconomic developments around the episodes of
financial stress.
43
A number of recent papers examine the links between house price fluctuations and macroeconomic
outcomes. For example, Cecchetti (2006) also reports that house price booms have adverse effects on
growth prospects. Using various methodologies, Cardarelli, Monacelli, Rebucci, and Sala (2008)
examine the interactions between house prices and business cycles in OECD countries.
44
For this purpose, we simply use the quantile regressions, a widely used methodology to control for
the impact of outliers. We have also experimented with other robust methodologies to account for the
roles played by outliers, but our main results are preserved.
34
findings by Bordo, et al. (2001) who report that banking, currency and twin crises are
positively correlated with the severity of recessions (see also Cerra and Saxena, 2008).
45
IX. C
ONCLUSION
A. A Summary
Our analysis of the interactions between macroeconomic and financial variables around
various episodes of business and financial cycles suggests that these interactions play key
roles in determining the severity and duration of recessions. In particular, recessions
associated with credit crunches and house price busts appear to be deeper and last longer than
other recessions do. The durations of credit crunches and house price busts tend to be longer
than those of typical recessions, while the dynamics of the main components of domestic
absorption around these events are similar to those observed during recessions. In terms of
their impact on investment and the unemployment rate, credit crunches and house price busts
are more costly than equity price busts are, and equity price busts appear to be less
consistently associated with real sector outcomes.
We also provide a preliminary analysis of the determinants of the costs of recessions and the
special roles played by changes in financial variables during these episodes. In particular, we
employ basic regression models to examine how the amplitude of a recession is associated
with changes in financial variables. Our results suggest that the extent of declines in house
prices appears to most consistently influence the depth of recessions, even after taking
account for the changes in other financial variables, including credit and equity prices, and
various other controls.
B. Lessons for Today
The global economy has been experiencing a financial storm of historic proportions. What
are the lessons of our work for the implications of this crisis? The lessons from the earlier
episodes of recessions, crunches and busts we examined are sobering, suggesting that
recessions following this financial storm will likely be more costly than other recessions,
because they take place alongside simultaneous credit crunches and asset price busts.
Furthermore, although the effects of the current crisis have already been felt gradually around
the world, the past evidence suggests that its global dimensions are likely to intensify in the
coming months. Nevertheless, the nature of a recession in a particular country can be shaped
by many factors, including the financial health of its firms, banks, and households prior to the
recession and what policy measures authorities employ to mitigate its adverse effects.
Continued decisive policy actions at both the national and global levels could help meet the
evolving challenges.
45
We undertake some additional sensitivity tests to check the robustness of our regression results. For
example, we examine the inclusion of fixed effects to control for country-specific and time invariant
characteristics not included in our models. In addition, we consider the shape of the distribution of
our dependent variable and its possible impact on the nature of errors. Additional regressions to
address such considerations do not change the main messages from the baseline regression.
35
C. Caveats and Future Research
While our broad cross-country study sheds much new light on the implications of recessions,
crunches, and busts, it does come with its caveats. Being primarily an event study, no causal
inferences are made (or intended) as to how recessions come about, whether financial
variables affect macroeconomic outcomes or vice-versa, and how policies affect economic
and financial outcomes. Moreover, as mentioned before, an important caveat to our analysis
is that initial conditions, external developments in terms of both demand and supply, and
policy responses will affect the path an economy follows during a recession. We attempt to
control for some of these factors in our preliminary regressions, but nevertheless our analysis
makes clear that more work is needed to get a better grasp of the important macroeconomic
and financial linkages so as to be better informed on how to adjust policies and institutional
environments to lower the costs of recessions, and to make better forecasts on the shape of
economic outcomes.
For example, our analysis does not yet explore the channels through which financial and real
variables interact. As noted by a diverse set of theoretical studies, besides general wealth and
substitution effects, financial variables will impact the balance sheets of financial institutions,
firms and households, and thereby affect the extension of credit and thus the performance of
the real economy. While there has been some empirical work documenting the importance of
these channels in normal times, little is known about how they operate in a recession, which
could include Fisherian deflations.
This points to an exciting future research agenda. One additional approach to shed more light
on the channels would be to use individual firm data for a similarly large sample of countries.
For instance, we plan to examine the evolution of firm financial variables, especially credit
use, inventory and liquidity, by classes of firms, including firm size, degree of leverage and
other measures capturing the likely degree of firms being financially constrained. This will
allow one to investigate whether firms that are more dependent on external finance are hit
harder during recessions with credit contractions and housing busts than during normal
recessions.
In our future research, we also plan to focus on alternative metrics of economic activity, such
as various measures of output gap, studying whether there are different patterns in recessions
associated with financial stress or crisis episodes, and how various types of recessions
interact with global and emerging market cycles. Lastly, it would be useful to expand the
sample of countries by including emerging market economies to examine the global
dimensions of recessions.
36
REFERENCES
Artis, Michael, Massimiliano Marcellino, and Tommaso Proietti, 2002, “Dating the Euro
Area Business Cycle,” EUI Working Paper ECO No. 2002/24. (San Domenico,
Italy).
Artis, Michael J., Zenon G. Kontolemis, and Denise R. Osborn, 1997, “Business Cycles for
G-7 and European Countries,” Journal of Business, Vol. 70, 249–79.
Backus D.K., P.J. Kehoe, and F.E. Kydland, 1995, “International Business Cycles: Theory
and Evidence,” in Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, ed. by C. Plosser, 331–57,
(Princeton University Press).
Bernanke, Ben and Mark Gertler, 1989, “Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business
Fluctuations,” American Economic Review 79, 14-31.
Bernanke, Ben, Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist, 1996, “The Financial Accelerator and the
Flight to Quality,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 78, No. 1, (Feb.), 1-
15.
Bernanke, Ben S., and Cara S. Lown, 1991, “The Credit Crunch,” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity,2, 205–47.
Bernanke, Ben, Mark Gertler, and Mark Watson, 1997, “Systematic Monetary Policy and the
Effects of Oil Price Shocks,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol 1, 91-157.
Blanchard, Olivier J., 1993, “Consumption and the Recession of 1990-1991,” American
Economic Review, P&P, vol. 83(2), 270-74.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Stanley Fisher, 1989, Lectures on Macroeconomics, The MIT
Press (Cambridge, Massachusetts).
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Jordi Gali, 2007, “The Macroeconomic Effects of Oil Shocks:
Why are the 2000s So Different from the 1970s?,” NBER Working Papers 13368,
(Cambridge: Massachusetts).
Blanchard, Olivier J., and John Simon, 2001, “The Long and Large Decline in U.S. Output
Volatility,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 135-64.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Mark Watson, 1986, “Are All Business Cycles Alike?” in The
American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, edited by Robert J. Gordon.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 123-156.
Borio, Claudio, C. Furfine, and P. Lowe, 2001, “Procyclicality of Financial Systems and
Financial Stability,” BIS Papers No.1 (Basel, Switzerland: Bank for International
Settlements).
Borio, Claudio and Patrick McGuire, 2004, “Twin Peaks in Equity and House prices?,” BIS
Quarterly Review, March, 79-93. (Basel, Switzerland: Bank for International
Settlements).
Bry, Gerhard and Charlotte Boschan, 1971, Cyclical Analysis of Time Series: Selected
Procedures and Computer Programs, (New York: NBER).
37
Burns, Arthur F., and Wesley C. Mitchell, 1946, Measuring Business Cycles (New York:
National Bureau of Economic Research).
Calvo, Guillermo A., Alejandro Izquierdo, and Ernesto Talvi, 2006, "Phoenix Miracles in
Emerging Markets: Recovering without Credit from Systemic Financial Crises,"
NBER Working Paper No. 12101, (Cambridge: Massachusetts).
Canova, Fabio, 1998, “Detrending and Business Cycle Facts,” Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol. 41(3), 475-512.
Cardarelli, Roberto, Selim Elekdag, and Subir Lall, 2008, “Financial Stress and Economic
Downturns,” IMF World Economic Outlook, October, 129-158. (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Cardarelli Roberto, Tommaso Monacelli, Alessandro Rebucci and Luca Sala, 2008,
“Housing Finance, Housing Shocks, and the Business Cycle: Evidence from OECD
Countries,” Forthcoming IMF Working Paper, (Washington: International Monetary
Fund).
Carrol, Christopher, Misuzu Otsuka and Jirka Slacalek, 2006, “How Large is the Housing
Wealth Effect? A New Approach,” NBER Working Paper, 12746. (Cambridge,
Massachusetts).
Cecchetti, Stephen G, 2006, “Measuring the Macroeconomic Risks Posed by Asset Price
Booms,” in J.Y. Campbell (ed.) Asset Prices and Monetary Policy, University of
Chicago Press.
Cerra, Valerie, and Sweta Chaman Saxena. 2008, "Growth Dynamics: The Myth of
Economic Recovery, " American Economic Review 98(1), 439–57.
Claessens, Stijn, M. Ayhan Kose and Marco Terrones, 2008, “Recessions in the United
States: Domestic and Global Implications,” Forthcoming IMF Working Paper.
(Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Cochrane, John H., December 1994, “Shocks,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on
Public Policy, vol. 41(1), 295-364.
Cotis Jean-Philippe and Jonathan Coppel, 2005, "Business Cycle Dynamics in OECD
Countries: Evidence, Causes and Policy Implications," RBA Annual Conference
Volume, in: Christopher Kent & David Norman (ed.), The Changing Nature of the
Business Cycle Reserve Bank of Australia.
Crucini, Mario, M. Ayhan Kose, and Christopher Otrok, 2008, “What Are the Driving Forces
of International Business Cycles?” NBER Working Paper No: 14380.
Dell’Ariccia, Giovanni and Pietro Garibaldi, 2005, “Gross Credit Flows,” Review of
Economic Studies, Vol. 72, No. 3.
Ferguson, Roger W., 2005, “Recessions and Recoveries Associated with Asset-Price
Movements: What Do We Know?,” Speech given at the Stanford Institute for
Economic Policy Research, Stanford, California, (Washington, D.C. : Federal
Reserve Board).
38
Fisher, Irving, 1933, “The Debt-Deflation Theory of the Great Depressions,” Econometrica
1, 337-357.
Gordon, Robert J., 1986, The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, NBER
Studies in Business Cycles, Volume 25 (Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago
Press).
Hall, Robert E., 1993, “Macro Theory and the Recession of 1990-1991,The American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 83, No. 2, 275-279.
Hall, Robert E., 2005, “Separating the Business Cycle from other Economic Fluctuations”,
Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, August, 133-179.
Hall, Robert E., 2007, “How Much Do We Understand about the Modern Recession?
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2, 13-30.
Hall Viv B. and C. John McDermott, 2006, “The New Zealand Business Cycle: Return to the
Golden Days?,” Center for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Working Paper
21/2006. (New Zealand: Victoria University of Wellington).
Hamilton, James, 1989, “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time
Series and the Business Cycle,” Econometrica, Vol. 57, No. 2, 357-384.
Hamilton, James, 2003, Comment on “A comparison of two business cycle dating methods”
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 27, No. 9, 1691-1693
Hamilton, James, 2005, “Oil and the Macroeconomy,” Mimeo, prepared for the Palgrave
Dictionary of Economics.
Harding, Don and Adrian Pagan, 2002a, “Dissecting the Cycle: A Methodological
Investigation,” Journal of Monetary Economics Vol. 49, 365-381.
Harding, Don and Adrian Pagan, 2002b. “A Comparison of two Business Cycle Dating
Methods,” Journal of Economics Dynamics and Control, Vol. 27, 1681-1690.
Hansen, Gary D. and Edward C. Prescott, 1993, “Did Technology Shocks Cause the 1990-
1991 Recession?” The American Economic Review, P&P, Vol. 83, No. 2, 280-286.
Harding, Don and Adrian Pagan, 2006, “Measurement of Business Cycles,” The University
of Melbourne, Research Paper No. 966.
Helbling, Thomas and Marco E. Terrones, 2003, “Real and Financial Effects of Bursting
Asset Price Bubbles,” IMF World Economic Outlook, April. 61-94. (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Kashyap, Anil K. and Jeremy C. Stein, 2000, “What Do a Million Observations on Banks
Say about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?,” American Economic Review, 90,
June 2000, 407-428.
Kehoe, Timothy J. and Edward Prescott, 2002, “Great Depressions of the Twentieth
Century,” Review of Economics Dynamics, Vol.5(1), 1-18.
Kilian, Lutz, 2008, “The Economic Effects of Energy Price Shocks,” forthcoming in Journal
of Economic Literature.
39
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore, 1997, “Credit Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy
105, 211–248.
Kose, M. Ayhan, Christopher Otrok, and Charles Whiteman, 2003, “International Business
Cycles: World, Region, and Country Specific Factors,” American Economic Review,
Vol. 93, 1216–39.
Kose, M. Ayhan, Christopher Otrok and Eswar Prasad, 2008, “Global Business Cycles:
Convergence or Decoupling?,” IMF Working Paper 08/143. (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Kose, M. Ayhan, Christopher Otrok, and Charles Whiteman, 2008, “Understanding the
Evolution of World Business Cycles,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 75,
110-130.
Kose, M. Ayhan, Eswar S. Prasad, and Marco E. Terrones, 2003a, “How Does Globalization
Affect the Synchronization of Business Cycles?” American Economic Review, Papers
and Proceedings, Vol. 93, 5762
Kose, M. Ayhan, Eswar S. Prasad, and Marco E. Terrones, 2003b, “Financial Integration and
Macroeconomic Volatility,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 50, No. 1, 119-142.
Kydland, Finn E. and Edward C. Prescott. 1982. “Time to Build and Aggregate
Fluctuations.” Econometrica, Vol. 50, 1345-70.
Leamer, Edward, 2007, “Housing is the Business Cycle,” NBER Working Paper No. 13428.
(Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Lown, Cara and Donald P. Morgan, 2006, "The Credit Cycle and the Business Cycle: New
Findings Using the Loan Officer Opinion Survey," Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, Vol 38, No 6, 1575-1597.
Mendoza, Enrique and Marco E. Terrones, 2008, “An Anatomy of Credit Booms: Evidence
from Macro Aggregates and Micro Data.” NBER Working Paper No. 14049
(Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Mendoza, Enrique G, 2008, "Sudden Stops, Financial Crises and Leverage: A Fisherian
Deflation of Tobin's Q," NBER Working Paper No. 14444, (Cambridge:
Massachusetts).
Mishkin, Frederic S., 2007, “Housing and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism,” Finance
and Economics Discussion Series, Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary
Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C. 2007-40
Morsink, James, Thomas Helbling, and Stephen Tokarick, 2002, “Recessions and
Recoveries,IMF World Economic Outlook, April, 104-137. (Washington:
International Monetary Fund).
Muellbauer, John, 2007, “Housing, Credit and Consumer Expenditure,” paper prepared for
presentation at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City 31st Economic Policy
Symposium, “Housing, Housing Finance and Monetary Policy,” Jackson Hole,
Wyoming, August 31–September 1.
40
Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff, 1999, Foundations of International
Macroeconomics. The MIT Press. (Cambridge, MA).
Pagan, Adrian and Kirill Sossounov, 2003, “A Simple Framework for Analyzing Bull and
Bear Markets,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 18, 23-46.
Perry, George L., Charles L. Schultze, Benjamin M. Friedman, and James Tobin, 1993,“Was
This Recession Different? Are They All Different?” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, Vol. 1993, No. 1, 145-211.
Plosser, Charles I. 1989. “Understanding Real Business Cycles.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 3, 51-77.
Reinhart, Carmen and Kenneth Rogoff, 2008, “This Time is Different: A Panoramic View of
Eight Centuries of Financial Crises,” NBER Working Paper, No. 13882. (Cambridge,
MA: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Romer, Christina, 1999, “Changes in Business Cycles: Evidence and Explanations,” Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13, Number 2, 23-44.
Romer, Christina and David H. Romer, 1994, “What Ends Recessions?”, NBER
Macroeconomics Annual 1994, 13-79. (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research).
Stock, James H. and Mark W. Watson, 1999, “Business Cycle Fluctuations in US
Macroeconomic Time Series.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics, Volume 1. Ed. by
J.B. Taylor and M. Woodford. Elsevier Science B.V.
Stock, James H. and Mark W. Watson, 2003. "Has the Business Cycle Changed?,"
Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 9-56.
Terrones, Marco E., 2004, “The Global House Price Boom,” IMF World Economic Outlook,
September, 71-136. (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Zarnowitz, Victor, 1985. "Recent Work on Business Cycles in Historical Perspective:
Review of Theories and Evidence," Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 23, No. 2,
523-580.
Zarnowitz, Victor, 1999, “Theory and History Behind Business Cycles: Are the 1990s the
Onset of a Golden Age?,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13, No. 2, 69-90.
41
Appendix: Database
Variable Variable Definition Source
Output Gross domestic product, volume; 1960:1-2007:4* OECD
Consumption Private final consumption expenditure, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
Government Consumption Government final consumption expenditure, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
(except Spain: 1961:1-2007:4)
Investment Gross fixed capital formation, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
Residential FCF Private residential fixed capital formulation, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
(except Canada: 1961:1-2007:4, France: 1963:1-2007:4,
New Zealand: 1961:3-2007:4, Portugal: 1988:1-2007:4)
Nonresidential FCF Private nonresidential fixed capital formulation, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
(except Canada: 1961:1-2007:4, France: 1963:1-2007:4,
UK: 1962:1-2007:4, Denmark: 1971:1-2007:4,
New Zealand: 1961:3-2007:4, Norway: 1962:1-2007:4,
Portugal: 1988:1-2007:4, Switzerland: 1961:1-2007:4)
Total FCF Private total fixed capital formulation, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
(except Canada: 1961:1-2007:4, Denmark: 1971:1-2007:4,
France: 1963:1-2007:4, New Zealand: 1961:3-2007:4,
Norway: 1962:1-2007:4, Portugal: 1977:1-2007:4,
Spain: 1964:1-2007:4, Switzerland: 1961:1-2007:4,
UK: 1962:1-2007:4)
Industrial Production Industrial production; 1960:1-2007:4 IFS
Generally, the coverage of industrial production indices comprises mining
and quarrying, manufacturing and electricity, and gas and water, according
to the UN international Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC). For most
OECD countries, the data come from the OECD database.
Exports Exports of good and services, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
Imports Imports of good and services, volume; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD
Export Prices Export unit values; 1960:1-2007:4 IFS
(except Portugal: 1983:1-2007:4, Switzerland: 1961:1-2007:4)
Indices for Unit Value of Exports are Laspeyres, with weights derived from
the data for transactions.
Import Prices Import unit values; 1960:1-2007:4 IFS
(except Belgium: 1993:1-2007:4, France: 1989:4-2007:4,
Greece: 1961:1-2007:4, Switzerland: 1961:1-2007:4)
Indices for Unit Value of Exports are Laspeyres, with weights derived from
the data for transactions.
Net Export-GDP ratio Net exports/GDP; 1960:1-2007:4 Both net exports and GDP
(except France: 1963:1-2007:4) are from OECD.
Current Account - GDP Ratio Current account balances/GDP; 1960:1-2007:4 (1) Current account balances
(except Austria: 1970:1-2007:4, Belgium: 1975:1-2007:4, are from OECD and GDS;
Denmark: 1988:1-2007:4, Finland: 1975:1-2007:4, (2) GDP is from OECD.
France: 1975:1-2007:4, Germany: 1971:1-2007:4,
Greece: 1975:1-2007:4, Ireland: 1975:1-2007:4,
Italy: 1971:1-2007:4, Japan: 1968:1-2007:4,
Netherlands: 1967:1-2007:4, New Zealand: 1971:1-2007:4,
Norway: 1975:1-2007:1, Portugal: 1975:1-2007:4,
Spain: 1975:1-2007:4, Sweden: 1975:1-2007:4,
Switzerland: 1972:1-2007:4)
42
Appendix: Database contd ......
Variable Variable Definition Source
NEER Nominal effective exchange rate; 1960:1-2007:4 IFS
(except Australia 1975:1-2007:4, New Zealand 1975:1-2007:4,
Portugal 1975:1-2007:4)
A nominal effective exchange rate index represents the ratio (expressed on
the base 2000=100) of an index of a currency's period-average exchange
rate to a weighted geometric average of exchange rates for the currencies
of selected countries and the euro area.
REER Real effective exchange rate; 1980:1-2007:4 IFS
A real effective exchange rate index represents a nominal effective
exchange rate index adjusted for relative movements in national price or
cost indicators of the home country, selected countries, and the euro area.
House Prices Nominal house prices deflated using CPI (BIS data only); 1970:1-2007:4 OECD and BIS (Austria,
(except Austria: 1986:3-2007:4, Belgium: 1988:1-2007:4, Belgium, Greece and
Greece: 1993:4-2007:4, Portugal: 1988:1-2007:4, Portugal)
Spain: 1971:1-2007:4)
Stock Prices Share Price (Index) deflated using Consumer Price Index; 1960:1-2007:4 Both Share Price (Index) and
1960:1-2007:4 Consumer Price Index are
(except Denmark: 1970:1-2007:4, Greece: 1994:1-2007:4, from IFS.
New Zealand: 1961:1-2007:4, Portugal: 1988:1-2007:4,
Spain: 1961:1-2007:4)
Indices shown for Share Prices generally relate to common shares
of companies traded on national or foreign stock exchanges. All
reported indices are adjusted for changes in quoted nominal capital
of companies. Indices are, in general, base-weighted arithmatic
averages with market value of outstanding shares as weights.
Real Credit Nominal credit deflated using Consumer Price Index; 1960:1-2007:4 (1) Nominal credit is from
(except Italy: 1970:1-2007:4, UK: 1963:1-2007:4, IFS and Datastream;
Spain:1972:1-2007:4, Sweden: 1969:4-2007:4, (2) Consumer Price Index
Switzerland: 1964:1-2007:4) is from IFS.
Nominal credit from IFS is generally titled "Claims on Private Sector",
"Claims on Other Resident Sector", etc. Nominal credit from Datasteam
is generally titled "Loans to Resident Private Sector", "Lending to
Enterprises and Individuals", etc.
Short-term Real Interest Rate Treasury bill rate deflated using inflation rate; 1960:1-2007:4 (1) Short-term nominal interest
Treasury Bill Rate is the rate at which short-term securities are issued or rate is from IFS;
traded in the market. (2) Inflation rate is the annual
(except Australia 1969:3-2007:4) growth rate of CPI (from IFS).
Long-term Real Interest Rate Government bond yield deflated using inflate rate; 1960:1-2007:4 (1) Long-term nominal interest
Government Bond Yield refers to one or more series representing yields rate is from IFS;
to maturity of government bonds or other bonds that would indicate (2) Inflation rate is the annual
longer -term rates. growth rate of CPI (from IFS).
(except Austria 1970:1-2007:4, Finland 1970:1-2007:4,
Greece 1992:4-2007:4, Spain 1970:1-2007:4)
Unemployment Rate Unemployment rate; 1960:1-2007:4 OECD, GDS, HAVER,
The unemployment rate is the ratio of number of persons unemployed DATASTREAM and BLOOMBERG
and the number of persons in the labour force. The labour force is the
sum of the numbers of persons employed and unemployed. The criteria
for a person to be considered as unemployed or employed are defined
by the ILO guidelines.
Inflation Rate Inflation rate; 1960:1-2007:4 CPI is from IFS.
Inflation rate is calculated as [CPI(quarter i, year t)
/CPI(quarter i, year t-1)-1]*100, where i=1,2,3,4.
* The series for US is from 1960:1-2008:1; same for all other series.
43
Figure 1. Associations between Recessions, Crunches and Busts
(number of events in each event category)
N
otes: The rectangle shows the distribution of 122 recession episodes in the sample into those associated
with crunches and busts (76) and those associated with none (46). Out of 122 recessions, 18 are associated
with credit crunches, 34 are with house price busts, and 45 are with equity price busts. 46 recessions are not
associated with either a crunch or bust episode.
10
31
18
9
3 1
4
46
Credit Crunches
House
Price Busts
Equity
Price Busts
Recessions
44
Figure 2. Recessions: Duration and Amplitude
(share of total sample, percent)
a. Duration and Amplitude: Full Period (1960:1-2007:4)
0
10
20
30
40
50
Short (2 quarters) Medium (3-4 quarters) Long (5+ quarters)
Severe
Moderate
Mild
b. Duration: Sub-periods
0
10
20
30
40
50
Short (2 quarters) Medium (3-4 quarters) Long (5+ quarters)
1986-07
1973-85
1960-72
c. Amplitude: Sub-periods
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
Mild (0-0.8%) Moderate (0.8-3.2%) Severe (>3.2%)
1986-07
1973-85
1960-72
Notes: Share of total number of recessions falling in particular categories. Duration is the number of
quarters from a peak to the next trough of a recession. Amplitude is the percent change in output
from a peak to the next trough of a recession.
45
Figure 3. Recessions in OECD Countries
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
Output
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12-8-404812
Private Consumption
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12-8-404812
Total Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Non-Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12-8-404812
Industrial Production
-8
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
-12-8-404812
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a recession begins
(peak in the level of output).
46
Figure 3. Recessions in OECD Countries (continued)
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
Exports
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Imports
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Net Exports/GDP
-4
-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
4
-12-8-404812
Current Account Balance/GDP
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
-12-8-404812
Inflation Rate
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
-12-8-404812
Unemployment Rate
0
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
-12-8-404812
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a recession begins
(peak in the level of output). Inflation rate, unemployment rate, net exports/GDP, and
current acount balance are the level of the respective variable in percent.
47
Figure 3. Recessions in OECD Countries (continued)
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
House Prices
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Equity Prices
-45
-30
-15
0
15
30
45
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Credit
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a recession begins
(peak in the level of output).
48
Figure 4. Synchronization of Recessions
(Share of countries experiencing recessionary episodes of output,
consumption and investment, percent)
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
1960q1
1965q1
1970q1
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
2000q1
2005q1
Output
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
1960q1
1965q1
1970q1
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
2000q1
2005q1
Output
Consumption
0
20
40
60
80
1960q1
1965q1
1970q1
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
2000q1
2005q1
Output
Investment
Notes: Share of countries experiencing recessions in output, consumption and investment.
Shaded bars indicate periods of U.S. recessions.
49
Figure 5. Synchronization of Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines
(Share of countries experiencing credit contractions or asset price declines, percent)
0
20
40
60
80
1960q1
1965q1
1970q1
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
2000q1
2005q1
Output
House Prices
0
20
40
60
80
100
1960q1
1965q1
1970q1
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
2000q1
2005q1
Output
Equity Prices
0
20
40
60
1960q1
1965q1
1970q1
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
2000q1
2005q1
Output
Credit
Notes: Share of countries experiencing episodes of credit contractions, house price
declines and equity price declines. Shaded bars indicate periods of U.S. recessions.
50
Figure 6. Credit Crunches in OECD Countries
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
Output
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Private Consumption
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Total Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Non-Residential Investment
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Inflation Rate
0
5
10
15
20
25
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a crunch begins
(peak in the level of credit). Inflation rate is the level of the inflation rate in percent.
51
Figure 6. Credit Crunches in OECD Countries (continued)
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
House Prices
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Equity Prices
-45
-30
-15
0
15
30
45
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Credit
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Unemployment Rate
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
-12-8-404812
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a crunch begins
(peak in the level of credit). Unemployment rate is the level of the unemployment rate in
percent.
52
Figure 7. House Price Busts in OECD Countries
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
Output
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Private Consumption
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Total Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12-8-404812
Non-Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Inflation Rate
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
-12-8-404812
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a bust begins (peak
in the level of house price). Inflation rate is the level of the inflation rate in percent.
53
Figure 7. House Price Busts in OECD Countries (continued)
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
House Prices
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
25
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Equity Prices
-45
-30
-15
0
15
30
45
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Credit
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Unemployment Rate
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a bust begins (peak
in the level of house price). Unemployment rate is the level of the unemployment rate in
percent.
54
Figure 8. Equity Price Busts in OECD Countries
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
Output
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12-8-404812
Private Consumption
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
-12-8-404812
Total Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Non-Residential Investment
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-12-8-404812
Inflation Rate
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
-12-8-404812
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines
correspond to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a bust begins (peak
in the level of equity price). Inflation rate is the level of the inflation rate in percent.
55
Figure 8. Equity Price Busts in OECD Countries (continued)
(Percent change from a year earlier unless otherwise noted; zero denotes peak; x-axis in quarters)
House Prices
-8
-6
-4
-2
0
2
4
6
8
10
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Equity Prices
-40
-20
0
20
40
60
-12-8-404812
Credit
-4
0
4
8
12
16
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Unemployment Rate
0
2
4
6
8
10
-12 -8 -4 0 4 8 12
Notes: The solid line denotes the median of all observations while the dotted lines correspond
to upper and lower quartiles. Zero is the quarter after which a bust begins (peak in the level of
equity price). Unemployment rate is the level of the unemployment rate in percent.
56
Table 1.A. Recessions: Summary Statistics
Country Number of Duration Proportion Amplitude Cumulative Number of Duration Amplitude Cumulative
Recessions of time Loss Severe Recessions Loss
in Recession
G-7
Canada 3 4.00 0.06 -2.84 -6.45 2 5.00 -4.13 -9.50
France 4 3.50 0.07 -1.27 -2.57 ... ... ... ...
Germany 8 3.25 0.13 -1.41 -2.56 1 4.00 -3.37 -4.90
Italy 9 3.11 0.15 -1.34 -2.67 1 3.00 -3.84 -7.94
Japan 3 4.67 0.07 -2.38 -7.39 1 8.00 -3.35 -15.38
United Kingdom 5 4.20 0.11 -3.11 -8.44 2 5.00 -4.77 -13.42
United States 7 3.43 0.12 -1.67 -3.16 ... ... ... ...
Other
Australia 7 3.43 0.12 -1.65 -3.50 1 7.00 -3.89 -12.70
Austria 6 2.50 0.08 -1.08 -1.60 ... ... ... ...
Belgium 7 2.86 0.10 -1.00 -1.53 ... ... ... ...
Denmark 7 4.14 0.15 -1.76 -4.11 1 7.00 -3.17 -9.58
Finland 5 4.60 0.12 -3.93 -22.51 1 13.00 -12.75 -102.76
Greece 8 3.50 0.15 -6.45 -11.83 6 3.67 -7.87 -14.63
Ireland 3 2.67 0.04 -0.90 -1.41 ... ... ... ...
Netherlands 5 4.00 0.10 -2.20 -0.82 2 2.50 -3.37 -4.32
New Zealand 12 3.83 0.24 -5.94 -14.74 9 3.11 -7.31 -12.04
Norway 3 2.67 0.04 -1.99 -2.99 ... ... ... ...
Portugal 4 4.50 0.09 -3.38 -6.68 1 5.00 -6.03 -12.19
Spain 4 3.00 0.06 -1.12 -2.76 ... ... ... ...
Sweden 3 7.33 0.11 -3.87 -15.17 1 12.00 -5.64 -24.23
Switzerland 9 3.56 0.17 -2.28 -6.86 1 7.00 -9.81 -42.81
Country Group
OECD
Median 5.00 3.00 0.11 -1.87 -3.04 1.00 4.00 -4.89 -9.94
Mean 5.81 3.64 0.11 -2.63 -6.40 2.14 4.70 -6.31 -16.10
G-7
Median 5.00 3.00 0.11 -1.59 -2.99 1.00 4.00 -3.46 -7.94
Mean 5.57 3.56 0.10 -1.83 -4.12 1.40 5.00 -4.05 -10.58
Other
Median 5.50 3.00 0.11 -2.01 -3.08 1.00 4.00 -6.03 -10.29
Mean 5.93 3.67 0.11 -3.01 -7.47 2.56 4.61 -7.00 -17.79
All Recessions Severe Recessions
Notes: Duration is the number of quarters between a peak and the next trough of a recession. Proportion of time
in recession refers to the ratio of the number of quarters in which the economy is in recession over the full
sample period. Amplitude is the percent change in output from a peak to the next trough of a recession.
Cumulative loss combines information about the duration and amplitude to measure the overall cost of a
recession and is expressed in percent. Severe recessions are those in which the peak-to-trough decline in output
is in the top 25 percent of all recession-related output declines. Country-specific data are means. Country-group
data are means/medians.
57
Table 1.B. Recessions: Summary Statistics
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
All Severe Other All Severe Other
Recessions Recessions Recessions Recessions Recessions Recessions
A. Output
Duration
1/
3.00 4*** 3.00 3.64 4.7** 3.29
Amplitude -1.87 -4.89*** -1.33 -2.63 -6.31*** -1.43
Cumulative Loss -3.04 -9.94*** -2.05 -6.40 -16.1*** -1.43
B. Components of Output
Consumption -0.07 -1.19* 0.05 -0.16 -1.21* 0.18
Total Investment -4.15 -9.73** -3.65 -5.93 -11.35** -4.19
Residential Investment -4.08 -12.6*** -2.56 -6.64 -15.52*** -3.78
Non-residential Investment -3.63 -7.38* -3.19 -5.10 -9.11* -3.78
Exports -0.65 -4.11*** 0.50 -0.74 -6.33*** 1.08
Imports -3.82 -9.18*** -2.58 -4.20 -9.41** -2.50
Net Export (% of GDP)
2/
0.62 1.61 0.48 0.76 0.79 0.75
Current Account (% of GDP)
2/
0.47 0.98 0.45 0.56 0.70 0.51
C. Other Macroeconomic Variables
Industrial Production -4.14 -7.01*** -2.89 -3.99 -7.35*** -3.07
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.60 1.7*** 0.50 1.10 2.88** 0.77
Inflation Rate
2/
-0.29 0.01 -0.31 -0.27 -0.13 -0.32
D. Financial Variables
House Prices -2.31 -4.53 -2.00 -3.57 -7.15* -2.49
Equity Prices -5.49 -15.64*** -5.07 -4.25 -13.55** -1.85
Credit 0.99 0.89 0.99 1.66 1.95 1.57
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Severe recessions are those in which the peak-to-trough decline in output is in the top 25 percent of all
recession-related output declines. Other recessions refer to episodes that are not severe recessions. In each cell, the
mean (median) change in the respective variable from peak to trough of recessions is reported, unless otherwise
indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of severe recessions and
other recessions is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
58
Table 2.A. Credit Contractions: Basic Statistics
Credit Crunches
Country Number of Duration Proportion Amplitude Number of Duration Amplitude
Contractions of time Crunches
in Contraction
G-7
Canada 6 3.33 0.10 -5.31 2 4.50 -10.40
France 5 4.80 0.12 -5.42 ... ... ...
Germany 3 7.67 0.12 -2.20 ... ... ...
Italy 6 6.00 0.19 -5.89 1 15.00 -11.87
Japan 5 7.80 0.20 -4.61 1 25.00 -11.24
United Kingdom 7 3.29 0.12 -9.12 2 4.00 -21.36
United States 5 7.80 0.20 -8.03 2 13.50 -15.11
Other
Australia 5 3.40 0.09 -6.02 1 8.00 -20.17
Austria ... ... ... ... ... ... ...
Belgium 6 5.33 0.17 -4.73 1 13.00 -13.32
Denmark 6 8.67 0.27 -11.82 3 14.33 -19.42
Finland 4 8.25 0.17 -10.23 1 22.00 -33.91
Greece 8 4.50 0.19 -7.17 2 6.00 -13.97
Ireland 5 6.00 0.16 -9.52 1 5.00 -13.71
Netherlands 2 4.50 0.05 -10.54 1 7.00 -20.79
New Zealand 8 5.13 0.21 -10.14 4 6.25 -17.21
Norway 4 4.00 0.08 -4.38 1 8.00 -13.80
Portugal 8 5.50 0.23 -8.51 2 8.00 -22.03
Spain 3 9.67 0.15 -7.40 1 11.00 -9.52
Sweden 7 6.71 0.24 -8.71 1 24.00 -39.55
Switzerland 7 4.43 0.16 -3.07 ... ... ...
Country Group
OECD
Median 5.50 4.00 0.16 -4.22 1.00 8.00 -17.03
Mean 5.50 5.65 0.15 -7.23 1.59 10.30 -17.80
G-7
Median 5.00 4.00 0.12 -4.12 2.00 10.00 -11.86
Mean 5.29 5.51 0.15 -6.16 1.60 10.50 -14.60
Other
Median 6.00 4.00 0.16 -4.54 1.00 8.00 -17.12
Mean 5.62 5.71 0.15 -7.78 1.58 10.21 -19.15
Credit Contractions
Notes: Duration is the number of quarters between a peak and the next trough of a contraction. Proportion of time
in contraction refers to the ratio of the number of quarters in which credit is experiencing a contraction episode over
the full sample period. Amplitude is the percent change in credit from a peak to the next trough of a contraction.
Credit crunches correspond to peak-to-trough declines in credit that are in the top 25 percent of all episodes of credit
declines. Country-specific data are means. Country-group data are means/medians.
59
Table 2.B. Credit Contractions: Summary Statistics
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
AllCreditOther AllCreditOther
Contractions Crunches Contractions Contractions Crunches Contractions
A. Credit
Duration
1/
4.00 8*** 3.00 5.65 10.3*** 4.13
Amplitude -4.22 -17.03*** -3.40 -7.23 -17.8*** -3.79
B. Macroeconomic Variables
Output 1.82 2.64** 1.58 2.19 3.6* 1.73
Consumption 1.18 1.49 1.15 1.34 1.75 1.21
Total Investment -0.70 -5.63*** 0.19 -2.17 -6.67** -0.73
Residential Investment -1.39 -5.92** -0.09 -4.69 -13.22** -1.96
Non-residential Investment 0.02 -2.51* 0.21 -0.74 -3.16 0.04
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.37 1.65*** 0.20 0.92 2.01** 0.59
Inflation Rate
2/
0.08 -0.37 0.23 0.77 -0.09 1.05
C. Other Financial Variables
House Prices -1.98 -10.28** -0.85 -3.46 -9.07** -1.58
Equity Prices -2.65 6.28** -5.93 -1.12 15.02* -6.28
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Credit crunches correspond to peak-to-trough declines in credit that are in the top 25 percent of all episodes of
credit declines. Other contractions refer to episodes that are not credit crunches. In each cell, the mean (median)
change in the respective variable from peak to trough of the episodes of credit declines/crunches is reported, unless
otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of credit
crunches and other contractions is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
60
Table 3.A. House Price Declines: Basic Statistics
House Price Busts
Country Number of Duration Proportion Amplitude Number of Duration Amplitude
Declines of time Busts
in Decline
G-7
Canada 9 6.00 0.28 -7.82 1 16.00 -20.80
France 3 13.33 0.21 -12.85 2 18.50 -18.13
Germany 7 7.57 0.27 -4.52 ... ... ...
Italy 7 8.86 0.32 -15.09 3 14.00 -24.66
Japan 3 26.33 0.41 -25.04 2 38.50 -37.20
United Kingdom 4 11.25 0.23 -19.24 2 16.50 -30.25
United States 7 6.00 0.22 -4.62 ... ... ...
Other
Australia 9 6.56 0.31 -6.75 ... ... ...
Austria 3 13.67 0.21 -12.63 2 17.00 -16.75
Belgium 2 3.00 0.03 -1.67 ... ... ...
Denmark 5 10.80 0.28 -18.15 2 21.50 -36.23
Finland 6 9.00 0.28 -16.33 2 18.50 -40.00
Greece 1 3.00 0.02 -3.37 ... ... ...
Ireland 8 4.75 0.20 -7.66 2 10.00 -16.86
Netherlands 5 6.80 0.18 -12.54 1 18.00 -47.17
New Zealand 6 8.83 0.27 -9.79 1 25.00 -37.83
Norway 5 11.40 0.30 -12.53 1 25.00 -40.48
Portugal 5 7.00 0.18 -4.93 ... ... ...
Spain 6 7.67 0.24 -12.62 2 13.00 -24.85
Sweden 6 8.50 0.26 -12.93 2 16.00 -31.02
Switzerland 7 8.57 0.31 -11.90 3 17.00 -25.07
Country Group
OECD
Median 6.00 6.00 0.26 -5.99 2.00 16.50 -28.52
Mean 5.43 8.47 0.24 -10.80 1.87 18.43 -28.50
G-7
Median 7.00 6.00 0.27 -6.81 2.00 16.00 -26.43
Mean 5.71 9.38 0.28 -10.77 2.00 20.50 -26.59
Other
Median 5.50 5.50 0.25 -5.45 2.00 17.00 -29.61
Mean 5.29 7.99 0.22 -10.82 1.80 17.28 -29.56
House Price Declines
Notes: Duration is the number of quarters between a peak and the next trough of a decline. Proportion of time in
decline refers to the ratio of the number of quarters in which house prices are experiencing a decline episode over the
full sample period. Amplitude is the percent change in house prices from a peak to the next trough of a contraction.
House price busts correspond to peak-to-trough declines in house prices that are in the top 25 percent of all episodes
of house price declines. Country-specific data are means. Country-group data are means/medians.
61
Table 3.B. House Price Declines: Summary Statistics
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
All House Price Other All House Price Other
Declines Busts Declines Declines Busts Declines
A. House Prices
Duration
1/
6.00 16.5*** 4.00 8.47 18.43*** 5.23
Amplitude -5.99 -28.52*** -4.14 -10.80 -28.5*** -5.04
B. Macroeconomic Variables
Output 2.78 5.97*** 2.46 3.24 4.84 2.72
Consumption 2.34 3.77 2.21 2.79 3.53 2.56
Total Investment 0.72 -8.36*** 2.22 -0.58 -7.98*** 1.82
Residential Investment -4.08 -11.55*** -0.96 -6.31 -16.4*** -2.99
Non-residential Investment 2.00 -7.79*** 2.72 1.85 -4.22** 3.85
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.50 2.65*** 0.30 1.11 3.15*** 0.50
Inflation Rate
2/
0.02 -3.05*** 0.22 -0.49 -2.9*** 0.30
C. Other Financial Variables
Equity Prices 0.30 -1.90 0.30 7.34 23.33 2.14
Credit 3.93 2.11 4.23 4.96 4.58 5.08
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: House price busts correspond to peak-to-trough declines in house prices that are in the top 25 percent of all
episodes of house price declines. Other declines refer to episodes that are not house price busts. In each cell, the mean
(median) change in the respective variable from peak to trough of house price declines/busts is reported, unless
otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of house price
busts and other declines is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
62
Table 4.A. Equity Price Declines: Basic Statistics
Equity Price Busts
Country Number of Duration Proportion Amplitude Number of Duration Amplitude
Declines of time Busts
in Decline
G-7
Canada 16 4.25 0.35 -20.85 2 6.50 -44.13
France 11 6.64 0.38 -32.30 5 10.80 -48.40
Germany 14 6.71 0.49 -25.59 2 11.00 -53.33
Italy 10 10.70 0.55 -41.84 7 12.57 -53.02
Japan 15 5.93 0.46 -24.58 3 12.00 -45.02
United Kingdom 15 5.27 0.41 -22.61 2 12.50 -60.80
United States 14 5.21 0.38 -20.42 1 8.00 -47.90
Other
Australia 13 5.69 0.38 -25.60 3 7.00 -48.92
Austria 9 14.67 0.68 -28.38 2 30.00 -58.13
Belgium 14 6.14 0.45 -23.50 3 9.00 -43.35
Denmark 10 5.90 0.31 -29.82 3 10.67 -48.45
Finland 8 8.75 0.36 -36.91 3 17.33 -61.16
Greece 3 6.00 0.09 -30.39 1 13.00 -74.42
Ireland 11 7.00 0.40 -35.29 4 9.25 -55.36
Netherlands 11 6.00 0.34 -28.50 3 10.33 -50.04
New Zealand 10 7.70 0.40 -31.10 3 12.33 -61.69
Norway 12 6.50 0.40 -33.75 2 6.50 -52.64
Portugal 4 9.00 0.19 -43.18 2 12.00 -61.17
Spain 13 7.77 0.52 -25.93 1 28.00 -90.24
Sweden 10 8.00 0.41 -29.96 2 5.50 -41.45
Switzerland 11 7.18 0.41 -31.31 4 12.75 -55.30
Country Group
OECD
Median 11.00 5.00 0.40 -26.58 3.00 10.00 -50.27
Mean 11.14 6.91 0.40 -28.34 2.76 11.78 -53.23
G-7
Median 14.00 5.00 0.41 -23.63 2.00 10.00 -47.75
Mean 13.57 6.14 0.43 -25.89 3.14 11.18 -50.57
Other
Median 10.50 5.00 0.40 -29.58 3.00 9.50 -53.16
Mean 9.93 7.43 0.38 -30.02 2.57 12.14 -54.86
Equity Price Declines
Notes: Duration is the number of quarters between a peak and the next trough of a contraction. Proportion of time in
decline refers to the ratio of the number of quarters in which equity prices are experiencing a decline episode over the
full sample period. Amplitude is the percent change in equity prices from a peak to the next trough of a contraction.
Equity price busts correspond to peak-to-trough declines in equity prices that are in the top 25 percent of all episodes
of equity price declines. Country-specific data are means. Country-group data are means/medians.
63
Table 4.B. Equity Price Declines: Summary Statistics
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
All Equity Price Other All Equity Price Other
Declines Busts Declines Declines Busts Declines
A. Equity Prices
Duration
1/
5.00 10*** 4.00 6.91 11.78*** 5.30
Amplitude -26.58 -50.27*** -19.80 -28.34 -53.23*** -20.14
C. Macroeconomic Variables
Output 3.40 4.44*** 3.03 4.99 7.37** 4.20
Consumption 2.59 4.15*** 2.33 4.61 6.92** 3.86
Total Investment 3.54 0.56** 4.04 3.79 1.03* 4.69
Residential Investment 2.93 1.61 3.03 2.56 -0.31 3.47
Non-residential Investment 4.24 2.69 4.58 4.86 2.79 5.52
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.10 0.7*** 0.00 0.30 1.14*** 0.04
Inflation Rate
2/
0.29 0.41 0.21 0.64 1.10 0.49
B. Other Financial Variables
House Prices 1.25 4.66 0.84 1.98 3.76 1.33
Credit 5.15 9.62*** 4.46 9.66 17.16*** 7.23
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Equity price busts correspond to peak-to-trough declines in equity prices that are in the top 25 percent of all
episodes of equity price declines. Other declines refer to episodes that are not equity price busts. In each cell, the
mean (median) change in the respective variable from peak to trough of equity price declines/busts is reported, unless
otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of equity price
busts and other declines is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
64
Table 5. Credit Contractions and Asset Price Declines: Summary Statistics
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
Events Duration
1/
Amplitude Total Residential
N
on-Residential Unemployment
2/
Investment Investment Investment
(Mean) (Median) (Median) (Median) (Median) (Median)
A. Credit Contractions 5.65 -4.22 -0.70 -1.39 0.02 0.37
Credit Crunches 10.3*** -17.03*** -5.63*** -5.92** -2.51* 1.65***
Other Credit Contractions 4.13 -3.40 0.19 -0.09 0.21 0.20
B. House Price Declines 8.47 -5.99 0.72 -4.08 2.00 0.50
House Price Busts 18.43*** -28.52*** -8.36*** -11.55*** -7.79*** 2.65***
Other House Price Declines 5.23 -4.14 2.22 -0.96 2.72 0.30
C. Equity Price Declines 6.91 -26.58 3.54 2.93 4.24 0.10
Equity Price Busts 11.78*** -50.27*** 0.56** 1.61 2.69 0.7***
Other Equity Price Declines 5.30 -19.80 4.04 3.03 4.58 0.00
Notes: Credit crunches and asset price busts correspond to peak-to-trough declines in credit and asset prices that are in
the top 25 percent of all episodes of credit contractions and asset price declines, respectively. In each cell, the mean
(median) change in the respective variable from peak to trough of the episodes of credit declines/crunches, house price
declines/busts, and equity price declines/busts is reported, unless otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and ***
indicate that the difference between means (medians) of crunches/busts and other contractions/declines is significant at
the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
65
Table 6. Leads and Lags: Recessions, Crunches and Busts
(Number of Quarters)
Median Values Mean Values
A. Leads
1/
Credit Crunches 4.00 4.53
House Price Busts 3.00 4.08
Equity Price Busts 5.00 5.71
B. Lags
2/
Credit Crunches 2.00 2.29
House Price Busts 9.00 10.67
Equity Price Busts 0.00 3.10
1/
Number of quarters between the start of a crunch/bust and the
start of a recession.
2/
Number of quarters between the end of a recession and the end
of a crunch/bust.
66
Table 7. Recessions Associated with Credit Crunches
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
Without With With Without With With
Crunches Crunches Severe Crunches Crunches Severe
Crunches Crunches
A. Output
Duration
1/
3.00 3.00 3.00 3.64 3.78 4.33
Amplitude -1.82 -2.19 -2.7* -2.47 -3.71 -4.05
Cumulative Loss -2.87 -4.44* -6.15** -6.05 -8.85 -12.38
B. Components of Output
Consumption -0.04 -0.41 -0.58 -0.19 -0.16 0.79
Total Investment -3.98 -4.97 -3.83 -5.90 -5.61 -4.70
Residential Investment -3.72 -7.42 -8.16 -6.38 -8.92 -10.04
Non-residential Investment -3.58 -4.25 -1.66 -5.12 -4.00 -1.40
Exports -0.53 -1.82 -1.13 -0.65 -2.22 -2.01
Imports -3.64 -4.53 -5.23 -3.81 -6.08 -7.07
Net Export (% of GDP)
2/
0.48 1.06 1.17 0.67 1.10 1.48
Current Account (% of GDP)
2/
0.45 0.88 1.39 0.57 0.42 1.65
C. Other Macroeconomic Variables
Industrial Production -4.02 -5.68 -6.48** -3.84 -5.30 -6.58**
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.55 0.90 1.00 1.14 0.89 0.83
Inflation Rate
2/
-0.31 -0.33 0.53 -0.38 0.20 0.79
D. Financial Variables
House Prices -1.82 -4.04** -4.88 -3.08 -6.38 -8.11
Equity Prices -6.28 -2.47 7.88** -4.50 -1.19 6.78**
Credit 1.54 -4.25*** -4.85*** 2.82 -4.9*** -5.73**
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Severe credit crunches are those that are in the top half of all crunch episodes. In each cell, the mean (median)
change in the respective variable from peak to trough of recessions associated with credit crunches is reported, unless
otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of recessions
with credit crunches and recessions without credit crunches is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent
levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
67
Table 8. Recessions Associated with House Price Busts
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
Without With With Without With With
Busts Busts Severe Busts Busts Severe
Busts Busts
A. Output
Duration
1/
3.00 3.00 3.00 3.20 4.47** 4.6**
Amplitude -1.52 -2.18 -2.64** -1.98 -3.16* -4.05**
Cumulative Loss -2.25 -3.74*** -5.23*** -3.53 -10.38** -13.9*
B. Components of Output
Consumption 0.09 -0.73*** -1.16*** 0.14 -1.68*** -2.25***
Total Investment -3.98 -6.92* -6.92 -4.65 -9.24** -9.59
Residential Investment -2.68 -6.64** -7.47** -4.74 -10.92** -13.65**
Non-residential Investment -3.65 -6.82* -6.82 -4.04 -8.75* -7.83
Exports -1.09 0.66* 0.67 -1.02 0.96* 1.20
Imports -2.55 -5.27 -5.3* -2.18 -5.29* -6.13**
Net Export (% of GDP)
2/
0.39 1.29*** 1.29** 0.06 1.52*** 1.48**
Current Account (% of GDP)
2/
0.01 0.7** 0.6* 0.01 1.24** 1.23**
C. Other Macroeconomic Variables
Industrial Production -4.55 -4.21 -4.99 -4.20 -4.21 -4.73
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.50 1.3** 1.24** 0.78 1.82* 1.78
Inflation Rate
2/
-0.27 -0.73 -0.59 -0.35 -0.86 -0.14
D. Financial Variables
House Prices -0.82 -6.28*** -7.05*** -0.32 -9.39*** -11.17***
Equity Prices -7.12 -2.13 -5.58 -6.62 -0.47 -1.54
Credit 2.42 -0.5*** -0.94*** 3.62 -2.3*** -3.07***
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Severe house price busts are those that are in the top half of all bust episodes. In each cell, the mean (median)
change in the respective variable from peak to trough of recessions associated with house price busts is reported, unless
otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of recessions with
house price busts and recessions without house price busts is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels,
respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
68
Table 9. Recessions Associated with Equity Price Busts
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
Without With With Without With With
Busts Busts Severe Busts Busts Severe
Busts Busts
A. Output
Duration
1/
3.00 3.00 3.00 3.48 3.82 3.61
Amplitude -1.63 -1.98 -2.05 -2.00 -2.79 -3.16
Cumulative Loss -2.64 -3.08 -3.20 -4.67 -7.83 -9.36
B. Components of Output
Consumption -0.05 -0.09 -0.27 0.23 -0.89** -1.33**
Total Investment -3.17 -6.17** -6.12* -3.72 -9.02*** -9.07**
Residential Investment -3.74 -5.21 -5.57 -4.55 -9.8** -9.41
Non-residential Investment -3.19 -5.18** -4.95* -3.04 -8.56** -9.04**
Exports 0.48 -0.80 0.76 0.48 0.11 1.28
Imports -0.53 -5.29*** -5.44*** -0.97 -6.35*** -6.79***
Net Export (% of GDP)
2/
0.39 1.36** 1.63*** 0.15 1.34** 1.74***
Current Account (% of GDP)
2/
0.48 0.41 0.83 0.19 0.98 1.35*
C. Other Macroeconomic Variables
Industrial Production -3.79 -5.06** -4.75* -3.24 -5.3** -5.14**
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.60 0.60 0.60 0.97 1.33 1.06
Inflation Rate
2/
-0.32 -0.32 -0.55 -0.35 -0.53 -0.46
D. Financial Variables
House Prices -1.93 -3.17 -4.97** -2.14 -5.53* -6.85*
Equity Prices -0.80 -13.05*** -11.52*** 1.21 -12.39*** -8.89***
Credit 1.06 1.00 1.39 2.63 0.2* 1.10
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Severe equity price busts are those that are in the top half of all bust episodes. In each cell, the mean (median)
change in the respective variable from peak to trough of recessions associated with equity price busts is reported, unless
otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of recessions with
equity price busts and recessions without equity price busts is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent
levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
69
Table 10. Recessions Associated with Crunches and Busts: Summary Statistics
Events Duration
1/
Amplitude
2/
Cumulative Loss
2/
(Mean) (Median) (Median)
A. Recessions without Credit Crunches 3.64 -1.82 -2.87
Recessions with Credit Crunches 3.78 -2.19 -4.44*
Recessions with Severe Credit Crunches 4.33 -2.7* -6.15**
B. Recessions without House Price Busts 3.20 -1.52 -2.25
Recessions with House Price Busts 4.47** -2.18 -3.74***
Recessions with Severe House Price Busts 4.60** -2.64** -5.23***
C. Recessions without Equity Price Busts 3.48 -1.63 -2.64
Recessions with Equity Price Busts 3.82 -1.98 -3.08
Recessions with Severe Equity Price Busts 3.61 -2.05 -3.20
Notes: Severe credit crunches and equity/house price busts are those that are in the top half of all crunch and bust
episodes. In each cell, the mean (median) change in the respective variable from peak to trough of recessions associated
with equity price busts is reported, unless otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference
between means (medians) of recessions with equity price busts and recessions without equity price busts is significant at
the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Percent change.
70
Table 11. Recessions Associated with Oil Price Shocks
(Percent change unless otherwise indicated)
Without With With Without With With
Oil Oil Severe Oil Oil Oil Severe Oil
Shocks Shocks Shocks Shocks Shocks Shocks
A. Output
Duration
1/
3.00 3.00 3.00 3.67 3.62 3.91
Amplitude -1.78 -2.05 -2.57** -2.38 -2.91 -3.52*
Cumulative Loss -2.94 -3.14 -4.23** -5.42 -7.44 -9.32*
B. Components of Output
Consumption 0.19 -0.24* -0.54** 0.40 -0.73** -1**
Total Investment -3.19 -5.16 -6.17 -4.69 -7.24 -8.92**
Residential Investment -2.90 -5.64 -6.53** -3.62 -9.42** -11.97**
Non-residential Investment -2.85 -4.35 -5.67 -4.42 -6.05 -7.42
Exports 0.07 -1.26 -1.43* 0.16 -2.16 -2.66*
Imports -3.35 -4.77* -6.47*** -2.07 -6.01** -7.83**
Net Export (% of GDP)
2/
0.75 0.45 1.17 0.77 0.66 0.98
Current Account (% of GDP)
2/
0.50 0.35 0.28 0.58 0.42 0.39
C. Other Macroeconomic Variables
Industrial Production -3.55 -4.25** -5.71*** -3.01 -4.82** -5.73***
Unemployment Rate
2/
0.60 0.55 0.90 1.05 1.15 1.45
Inflation Rate
2/
-0.90 0.29*** 0.53*** -0.88 0.37** 0.44**
D. Financial Variables
House Prices -2.93 -1.83 -3.09 -2.73 -4.26 -5.97
Equity Prices -5.48 -4.56 -5.30 -3.94 -4.36 -5.19
Credit 0.93 1.07 0.52 2.63 0.77 0.16
Median Values Mean Values
Notes: Oil price shocks (severe oil price shocks) correspond to increases in oil prices that are in the top 25 percent (12.5
percent) of all annual oil price increases. In each cell, the mean (median) change in the respective variable from peak to
trough of recessions associated with oil price shocks (severe oil price shocks) is reported, unless otherwise indicated. The
symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between means (medians) of recessions with equity price busts and
recessions without equity price busts is significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
2/
Change in levels.
71
Table 12. Changes in Policy Variables
(Recessions, credit contractions and asset price declines; median values)
Events Short-Term Short-Term Government
Nominal Real Consumption
3/
Interest Rate
1/
Interest Rate
2/
A. Recessions -0.79 -0.70 1.79
Severe Recessions 0.00 -1.11 2.16
Other Recessions -0.94 -0.66 1.61
B. Credit Contractions -0.28 -1.03 3.04
Credit Crunches -1.50 -0.09 6.33***
Other Credit Contractions 0.00 -1.32 2.38
C. House Price Declines -0.70 -0.64 3.39
House Price Busts -3.16*** 0.21 9.07***
Other House Price Declines -0.20 -0.80 2.59
D. Equity Price Declines 0.09 -0.10 3.65
Equity Price Busts 0.28 -0.57 7.72***
Other Equity Price Declines 0.07 0.07 2.93
E. Recessions without Credit Crunches -0.87 -0.67 1.60
Recessions with Credit Crunches -0.84 -0.78 3.84***
Recessions with Severe Credit Crunches -0.73 -0.79 4.57***
F. Recessions without House Price Busts -0.91 -0.76 1.70
Recessions with House Price Busts -1.21 -0.64 1.95
Recessions with Severe House Price Busts -1.04 -0.78 2.12
G. Recessions without Equity Price Busts -0.80 -0.67 1.49
Recessions with Equity Price Busts -1.04 -0.77 2.14
Recessions with Severe Equity Price Busts -0.95 -0.71 2.16
H. Recessions without Oil Price Shocks -0.79 -0.61 1.85
Recessions with Oil Price Shocks -0.76 -0.82* 1.53
Recessions with Severe Oil Price Shocks -0.95 -1.11** 2.14
Notes: Severe recessions are those in which the peak-to-trough decline in output is in the top 25 percent of all
recession-related output declines. Credit crunches and asset price busts correspond to peak-to-trough contractions
in credit and declines in asset prices that are in the top 25 percent of all episodes of credit contractions and asset
price declines, respectively. Severe credit crunches and equity/house price busts are those that are in the top half
of all crunch and bust episodes. Other contractions and declines refer to episodes that are not crunches and busts,
respectively. In each cell, the mean (median) change in the respective variable from peak to trough of relevant
episodes is reported, unless otherwise indicated. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate that the difference between
means (medians) of crunches/busts/shocks and other contractions/declines is significant at the 10 percent, 5
percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively.
1/
Treasure bill interest rate. Change in levels.
2/
Ex-post real interest rate. Deflated with each country's CPI. Change in levels.
3/
Percent change.
72
Table 13.A. Cost of Recessions
(Percent change in real variables unless otherwise indicated
)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Credit 0.036 -0.090*** -0.088*** -0.060
[0.034] [0.033] [0.033] [0.040]
House Price 0.174*** 0.224*** 0.220*** 0.167***
[0.043] [0.049] [0.046] [0.052]
Equity Price 0.023* 0.016 0.011
[0.013] [0.010] [0.011]
Exports 0.109*** 0.073* 0.035 0.087** 0.083* 0.081*
[0.039] [0.042] [0.051] [0.040] [0.042] [0.042]
Initial Output 0.177** 0.192** 0.163** 0.173** 0.165* 0.163*
[0.074] [0.074] [0.080] [0.084] [0.086] [0.083]
Oil Price -0.006 -0.008* -0.002 -0.007 -0.006 -0.004
[0.005] [0.005] [0.005] [0.004] [0.004] [0.004]
Great Moderation -0.803 -0.981** -0.742 -1.010** -1.002** -0.952**
[0.560] [0.482] [0.546] [0.467] [0.462] [0.456]
Financial Crisis 0.133 -0.231 0.413 -0.068 -0.034 -0.209
[0.507] [0.432] [0.428] [0.385] [0.373] [0.369]
Duration of Recession 0.261**
[0.125]
Constant 1.888*** 1.292* 1.478** 1.039 1.001 0.280
[0.650] [0.689] [0.693] [0.679] [0.667] [0.769]
Adjusted R-squared 0.191 0.355 0.095 0.404 0.412 0.432
Number of observations 117 95 109 95 95 95
OLS
Regressions
Notes: The dependent variable is the amplitude of a recession, measured as the change in output from the
peak to the next trough of a recession. Credit, house price, equity price and exports refer to the changes in
the respective variable during recessions. Initial output is the level of output at the onset of the recession
minus the level of output two years before. Oil price is the price of oil at the onset of the recession minus
the oil price two years before. Great Moderation and Financial Crisis refer to the dummy variables
associated with the relevant periods. Robust standard errors are in brackets. The symbols *, **, and ***
indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
73
Table 13.B. Cost of Recessions
(Percent change in real variables unless otherwise indicated)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Credit 0.036 ... ... -0.087** -0.083** -0.052
[0.033] ... ... [0.035] [0.034] [0.041]
House Price ... 0.165*** ... 0.216*** 0.209*** 0.157***
... [0.043] ... [0.052] [0.047] [0.055]
Equity Price ... ... 0.028** ... 0.021** 0.015
... ... [0.014] ... [0.009] [0.011]
Exports 0.109*** 0.063 0.014 0.079* 0.070 0.076
[0.041] [0.047] [0.054] [0.045] [0.047] [0.047]
Initial Output 0.191* 0.198** 0.200** 0.179* 0.169* 0.171*
[0.100] [0.087] [0.099] [0.094] [0.097] [0.096]
Oil Price -0.007 -0.008* -0.003 -0.007 -0.005 -0.003
[0.005] [0.005] [0.004] [0.004] [0.004] [0.004]
Great Moderation -0.885* -1.001** -0.842* -1.024** -1.008** -0.941**
[0.525] [0.456] [0.502] [0.441] [0.435] [0.422]
Financial Crisis -0.015 -0.240 0.241 -0.077 -0.009 -0.097
[0.558] [0.456] [0.459] [0.408] [0.387] [0.361]
Government Consumption 0.008 0.062 0.157 0.050 0.080 0.135
[0.149] [0.164] [0.169] [0.154] [0.145] [0.153]
Short-Term Interest Rate 0.088 0.082 0.246 0.061 0.071 0.009
[0.154] [0.116] [0.151] [0.111] [0.107] [0.100]
Duration of Recession ... ... ... ... ... 0.297**
... ... ... ... ... [0.128]
Constant 1.831*** 1.294* 1.312* 1.055 1.039 0.316
[0.697] [0.693] [0.754] [0.693] [0.685] [0.744]
Adjusted R-squared 0.186 0.334 0.149 0.381 0.396 0.419
Number of observations 115 94 107 94 94 94
OLS
Regressions
Notes: The dependent variable is the amplitude of a recession, measured as the change in output from the peak to
the next trough of a recession. Credit, house price, equity price, exports, government consumption, and short-
term interest rate refer to the changes in the respective variable during recessions. Initial output is the level of
output at the onset of the recession minus the level of output two years before. Oil price is the price of oil at the
onset of the recession minus the oil price two years before. Great Moderation and Financial Crisis refer to the
dummy variables associated with the relevant periods. Robust standard errors are in brackets. The symbols *,
**, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
74
Table 14.A. Cost of Recessions
(Percent change in real variables unless otherwise indicated)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Credit 0.005 -0.054** -0.055*** -0.044**
[0.029] [0.025] [0.017] [0.020]
House Price 0.113*** 0.141*** 0.148*** 0.092***
[0.021] [0.029] [0.019] [0.025]
Equity Price 0.004 0.010 0.005
[0.012] [0.006] [0.007]
Exports 0.114*** 0.052* 0.059* 0.057* 0.057** 0.049**
[0.026] [0.029] [0.034] [0.033] [0.022] [0.023]
Initial Output 0.169*** 0.138*** 0.127** 0.116** 0.132*** 0.106***
[0.055] [0.042] [0.056] [0.048] [0.032] [0.033]
Oil Price -0.005 -0.006* -0.002 -0.003 -0.003 0.001
[0.005] [0.003] [0.004] [0.004] [0.002] [0.003]
Great Moderation -1.177** -0.849** -0.647 -0.633* -0.651** -0.504*
[0.504] [0.335] [0.449] [0.376] [0.251] [0.255]
Financial Crisis 0.561 0.390 0.748 0.560 0.537 0.568*
[0.679] [0.426] [0.576] [0.475] [0.333] [0.338]
Duration of Recession 0.265***
[0.075]
Constant 1.395** 1.156*** 1.069** 0.908** 0.835*** 0.127
[0.536] [0.392] [0.505] [0.442] [0.292] [0.364]
Pseudo R-squared 0.132 0.232 0.010 0.273 0.288 0.323
Number of observations 117 95 109 95 95 95
Quantile
Regressions
Notes: The dependent variable is the amplitude of a recession, measured as the change in output from the peak to
the next trough of a recession. Credit, house price, equity price and exports refer to the changes in the respective
variable during recessions. Initial output is the level of output at the onset of the recession minus the level of
output two years before. Oil price is the price of oil at the onset of the recession minus the oil price two years
before. Great Moderation and Financial Crisis refer to the dummy variables associated with the relevant periods.
Standard errors are in brackets. The symbols *, **, and *** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and
1% levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.
75
Table 14.B. Cost of Recessions
(Percent change in real variables unless otherwise indicated)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Credit -0.001 ... ... -0.075*** -0.060*** -0.028
[0.032] ... ... [0.019] [0.017] [0.018]
House Price ... 0.097*** ... 0.154*** 0.150*** 0.085***
... [0.015] ... [0.022] [0.020] [0.022]
Equity Price ... ... 0.010 ... 0.016** 0.005
... ... [0.012] ... [0.007] [0.006]
Exports 0.110*** 0.028 0.032 0.063** 0.041* 0.059***
[0.028] [0.020] [0.034] [0.024] [0.021] [0.021]
Initial Output 0.121* 0.145*** 0.152*** 0.123*** 0.162*** 0.120***
[0.065] [0.030] [0.057] [0.037] [0.035] [0.031]
Oil Price -0.003 -0.006** 0.000 -0.003 -0.003 0.001
[0.005] [0.002] [0.004] [0.003] [0.003] [0.002]
Great Moderation -1.025* -0.441** -0.413 -0.446* -0.353 -0.606***
[0.531] [0.220] [0.453] [0.267] [0.253] [0.220]
Financial Crisis 0.501 0.371 0.861 0.729** 0.582* 0.493*
[0.719] [0.284] [0.558] [0.365] [0.338] [0.294]
Government Consumption -0.051 -0.035 0.070 0.101 0.052 0.159***
[0.088] [0.052] [0.083] [0.064] [0.058] [0.058]
Short-Term Interest Rate 0.052 0.096** 0.167* 0.043 0.083* 0.020
[0.092] [0.044] [0.090] [0.056] [0.050] [0.045]
Duration of Recession ... ... ... ... ... 0.344***
... ... ... ... ... [0.075]
Constant 1.283** 0.703*** 0.720 0.710** 0.428 0.061
[0.571] [0.260] [0.505] [0.318] [0.298] [0.320]
Pseudo R-squared 0.135 0.243 0.111 0.273 0.288 0.330
Number of observations 115 94 107 94 94 94
Quantile
Regressions
Notes: The dependent variable is the amplitude of a recession, measured as the change in output from the peak to
the next trough of a recession. Credit, house price, equity price, exports, government consumption, and short-
term interest rate refer to the changes in the respective variable during recessions. Initial output is the level of
output at the onset of the recession minus the level of output two years before. Oil price is the price of oil at the
onset of the recession minus the oil price two years before. Great Moderation and Financial Crisis refer to the
dummy variables associated with the relevant periods. Standard errors are in brackets. The symbols *, **, and
*** indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
1/
Number of quarters.