NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
BIAS IN CABLE NEWS:
REAL EFFECTS AND POLARIZATION
Gregory J. Martin
Ali Yurukoglu
Working Paper 20798
http://www.nber.org/papers/w20798
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
December 2014
We thank Tom Clark, Greg Crawford, Ruben Enikopolov, Matthew Gentzkow, Ben Golub, Marit
Hinnosaar, Kei Kawai, Robin Lee, Claire Lim, Paul Oyer, Ariel Pakes, Jesse Shapiro, Michael Sinkinson,
Gaurav Sood, Daniel Stone, and seminar and workshop participants at Boston College, Boston University,
the BFI Media and Communications Conference, Emory, Harvard, NYU Stern, Stanford GSB, the
Wallis Political Economy Conference, and the Workshop on Media Economics for comments and
suggestions, and Carlos Sanchez-Martinez for excellent research assistance. The views expressed herein
are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-
reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official
NBER publications.
© 2014 by Gregory J. Martin and Ali Yurukoglu. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to
exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including
© notice, is given to the source.
Bias in Cable News: Real Effects and Polarization
Gregory J. Martin and Ali Yurukoglu
NBER Working Paper No. 20798
December 2014
JEL No. D72,D83,L82
ABSTRACT
We jointly measure the persuasive effects of slanted news and tastes for like-minded news. The key
ingredient is using channel positions as exogenous shifters of cable news viewership. Local cable positions
affect viewership by cable subscribers. They do not correlate with viewership by local satellite subscribers,
who are observably similar to cable subscribers. We estimate a model of voters who select into watching
slanted news, and whose ideologies evolve as a result. We estimate that Fox News increases the likelihood
of voting Republican by 0.9 points among viewers induced into watching four additional minutes per
week by differential channel positions.
Gregory J. Martin
Tarbutton Hall
1555 Dickey Dr.
Atlanta, GA 30322
Ali Yurukoglu
Graduate School of Business
Stanford University
Stanford, CA 94305
and NBER
1 Introduction
Political observers across the ideological spectrum routinely make allegations of media
bias and its detrimental effect on society. Two of the three 24-hour cable news channels,
the Fox News Channel and MSNBC, are frequent targets of such allegations. In this
paper, we address two questions about cable news. First, how much does consuming
slanted news, like the Fox News Channel, alter the propensity of an individual to
vote Republican in Presidential elections, if at all? Second, how intense are consumer
preferences for cable news that is slanted towards their own ideology?
The answers to these questions are key inputs for designing optimal public pol-
icy towards the media sector. If consumers simply prefer news that resonates with
their pre-existing ideology, as in Mullainathan and Shleifer (2005) and Gentzkow and
Shapiro (2010), then the news media sector is similar to any other consumer product,
and should be treated as such by public policy. However, if consuming news with a
slant alters the consumer’s ideology, then public policy towards the news media sector
becomes more complex.
1
In particular, if news consumption alters ideology, and con-
sumers have a taste for like-minded news, then the existence of slanted news could lead
to a polarizing feedback loop: an “echo chamber” where partisans can reinforce and
strengthen their initial biases.
2
Furthermore, an interested party could potentially in-
fluence the political process by owning or controlling media outlets.
3
Such concerns led
the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) to condition approval of the merger
of Comcast Corporation and NBC Universal in 2010 on the requirement that Comcast
take steps to promote independent news services.
4
Differentiating the taste mechanism from the influence mechanism is difficult in ob-
servational data. The analyst observes a positive correlation between the propensity to
1
Gentzkow and Shapiro (2008) detail the complexities in designing optimal regulatory policy for media
markets.
2
Gentzkow and Shapiro (2011) indicate that current media consumption tends to be balanced across
ideologically slanted sources. This paper identifies trends suggesting that the “echo chamber” scenario may
be increasing in relevance.
3
Existing evidence from Gentzkow and Shapiro (2010) shows that owner partisanship is not an important
determinant of newspaper slant. The sample size is too small to test this hypothesis in the cable news case.
4
The condition required that Comcast move “independent” news channels such as Bloomberg Television
into “news neighborhoods.” This effectively required Comcast to move Bloomberg next to channels such as
MSNBC and CNN in their channel lineups.
2
vote Republican and hours spent watching Fox News. Were Fox News viewers already
predisposed to vote Republican, and the observed correlation driven by preference for
watching like-minded news? Or were some fraction of those viewers persuaded to vote
Republican as a consequence of watching Fox News?
The essential ingredient in our analysis is the use of the channel positions of news
channels in cable and satellite television lineups as instrumental variables. Variation
in channel positions causes some viewers to watch more or less of these channels. We
use the corresponding induced variation in time watched to estimate whether or not
watching slanted news changes voting behavior. We estimate that watching the Fox
News Channel (at its current ideological positioning) for four additional minutes per
week
5
increases the probability of intending to vote for the Republican presidential
candidate by 0.9 percentage points for voters induced into watching by variation in
channel position. Watching MSNBC (at its current ideological positioning) for four
additional minutes per week increases the probability of intending to vote for the
Democratic presidential candidate by about 0.7 percentage points for voters induced
into watching by variation in channel position.
As with any instrumental variables design, it is critical that the channel positions
for Fox News and MSNBC are exogenous, and not chosen to accord with local political
tastes. In Section 2, we describe turbulence in the cable industry in the years 1994-2000
that induced as good as random variation in channel positions across locations. We
then directly test and confirm the validity of the instrument by demonstrating that
the local cable channel positions of Fox News and MSNBC correlate strongly with the
channels’ viewership among cable subscribers but do not correlate with viewership by
satellite television subscribers in the same zip code.
Satellite viewership provides a useful placebo test because the two satellite providers
each use a single nationwide channel position lineup; thus, satellite subscribers’ viewing
decisions cannot be directly influenced by the local cable operator’s choice of lineup.
However, satellite subscribers’ observable characteristics and viewing tastes are highly
positively correlated with the characteristics and tastes of cable subscribers in the same
zip code. If the same correlation holds for unobservable political ideology, and if cable
5
Approximately four minutes per week is the additional time spent watching Fox News associated with
moving from a cable system with Fox News channel position at the 75
th
percentile of the distribution to one
with Fox News channel position at the 25
th
percentile.
3
companies endogenously choose channel positions to suit local political leanings, then
the channels’ positions on cable systems should predict viewing by satellite subscribers
in the same zip code. Our data reject this hypothesis. Across the set of news channels,
the coefficient estimates of cable channel positions on satellite viewing are close to zero.
Statistically, we can (1) not reject that effects of the cable positions on satellite viewing
are zero, and (2) reject that the effects of cable positions on satellite viewing are equal
to the effects of cable positions on cable viewing.
Our approach to quantifying the second object of interest, the preference for like-
minded news, follows Gentzkow and Shapiro (2010), who estimate this quantity in the
context of US daily newspapers. We first place the cable news channels on the ideo-
logical spectrum by quantifying how similar the language employed by the channels is
to the language employed by individual members of Congress. This method provides
a measure of ideological slant for each channel in each year. We measure the relation-
ship between changes in the slant measure over time and the characteristics of viewers
of these channels. A key source of variation in this exercise is MSNBC’s change in
business strategy towards offering more explicitly liberal content around 2006. Our
ideology estimates pick up this format switch - MSNBC closely tracks CNN in the
early 2000s, but then moves left following the format switch in 2006. We estimate
Fox News’ ideology to the right of CNN throughout the sample period, although the
distance between the two has been widening in the most recent years.
We conduct the analysis of these two questions in a unified framework. We model
consumer-voters who choose how much time to spend watching the cable news chan-
nels; whether to subscribe to cable, satellite or nothing at all; and for whom to vote
in presidential elections. Consumers’ allocation of time to television channels is gov-
erned by their preferences for the channels (which are a function of their ideology,
the channels’ ideologies, and their demographics), and the availability of the channels
(whether the cable operator carries them and, if so, the positions they occupy on the
channel lineup). Consumers’ ideologies evolve from their initial position depending on
how much time they allocate to watching channels of different ideologies. This process
culminates in a presidential election in which consumers choose for whom to vote.
We estimate the parameters of the model by simulated indirect inference. The cri-
terion function is the distance between two-stage least squares estimates of intention
to vote on demographics and hours watched of each channel, using channel positions
4
as instrumental variables, in the actual data and in data simulated from the model. In
addition to matching the second stage regression coefficients, we also match the first
stage (viewership equation) regression coefficients and the “mis-specified” OLS regres-
sion coefficients. We use data covering 1998 to 2008 from multiple sources including
(1) high quality channel lineup data that provides channel positions and availability by
zip code, provider, and year, (2) individual level viewership data on hours watched by
channel and year together with demographics and zip code, (3) individual level survey
data on intent to vote Republican in presidential elections together with demographics
and zip code, (4) county-level presidential vote shares, (5) broadcast transcripts of Fox
News, CNN, and MSNBC by year, and (6) the Congressional record by year.
We use the estimated model to quantitatively assess the degree of ideological polar-
ization induced by cable news and separately the effect of the entry of Fox News prior
to the year 2000 election. We find that cable news does increase polarization among
the viewing public. Furthermore, the increase in polarization depends critically on the
existence of both a persuasive effect and a taste for like-minded news. We estimate
that removing Fox News from cable television during the 2000 election cycle would
have reduced the average county’s Republican vote share by 1.6 percentage points.
This paper contributes to the empirical literature on the causes and effects of the
news media, particularly regarding political outcomes.
6
The closest papers to this
study are by DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) and Gentzkow and Shapiro (2010).
DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) seek to study the effects of Fox News by comparing
vote shares in locations with and without cable access to Fox News by November
2000, as partially measured by the Cable and Television Factbook data set. Our
contribution to this strand of the literature is to introduce a new and more credibly
exogenous source of variation, channel positions, to measure the effects of Fox News as
well other cable news like MSNBC, using correct data.
7
The use of channel positions
6
A number of papers have demonstrated that media usage or availability affects behavior. Amongst
others, Chiang and Knight (2011) find positive effects of unexpected newspaper endorsements on vote shares
for the endorsed candidate, Gentzkow (2006) finds decreased voter turnout from television access, Gerber
et al. (2009) find positive effects of newspaper exposure, regardless of slant, on Democratic vote shares in
the 2005 Virginia gubernatorial elections. Enikolopov et al. (2011) find that viewing an independent news
channel in Russia increased vote shares for the opposition parties and decreased overall turnout in 1999.
Lim et al. (2014) find that media coverage can affect criminal sentencing decisions for judges.
7
In Appendix A, we document that the data set used in DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) has severe mis-
measurement of Fox News availability. Nearly 40% of the “control group,” the locations that they consider
5
as instrumental variables could be useful for studying the effects of media consumption
in other contexts. In terms of results, we estimate a Fox News effect that is statistically
positive and quantitatively large whereas the DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) analysis,
updated to use the correct channel availability data, is inconclusive. We also find a
large MSNBC effect in 2008.
Our approach follows Gentzkow and Shapiro (2010) in several dimensions, includ-
ing the use of text analysis to measure media outlet slant. Like Gentzkow and Shapiro
(2010), we treat that measure as a characteristic over which consumers have heteroge-
neous tastes when choosing media consumption levels. Our contribution is to model
media consumption together with voting to separately measure tastes for like-minded
news and the influence of slanted media consumption on consumer ideology. The influ-
ence effect also interacts with the existence of tastes for like-minded news. Consumers
for whom both effects are present can be induced into feedback loops where they con-
sume slanted media, their ideologies then evolve in the direction of the slant, then their
taste for that slanted media increases, and so on in a loop.
2 Institutional Overview
During our study period of 1998-2008, most households had three options for television
service: subscribe to a cable (that is, a wire-based transmission) package, subscribe
to a satellite television package, or subscribe to neither and receive only over-the-air
broadcast signals.
8
In 2000, the vast majority of cable or satellite subscribers were
cable subscribers, but by 2008, satellite providers had a market share of about 30%.
Different locations have different cable providers such as Comcast, Time Warner Cable,
Cox, Cablevision, or Charter. The set of channels, or content, in a cable package varies
across providers and within providers across locations. A typical set of cable packages
as not having cable access to Fox News in 2000, did in fact have cable access to Fox News. 25% of the
control group had Fox News availability since 1998. Their data set simply had not been updated to reflect
Fox News’s arrival in those locations. We detail how their results change upon correcting the measurement
error in Appendix A.
8
Some households, for example households in remote rural areas, did not have a cable option. Some
households which did not have a direct line of sight due to physical obstructions like tall buildings, trees,
or steep slopes, did not have a satellite option. And some households, mostly in urban areas, had two
wire-based cable operators.
6
would have one Basic package which retransmits the over-the-air signals, an Expanded
Basic package which includes the top 40 to 80 cable channels such as ESPN, USA, TNT,
CNN, Nickelodeon, MTV, Comedy Central, and similar, and a digital package which
offers more niche content like the DIY Channel or the Tennis Channel. Throughout the
period, there were two nationwide satellite providers: DirecTV and the Dish Network.
Each satellite provider offers the same channel lineup and packages in all locations.
Cable content is produced by media conglomerates such as Viacom, News Corpora-
tion, ABC-Disney, or NBC Universal. The cable and satellite providers contract with
these firms to offer their content to subscribers. This bilateral contracting is the focus
of Crawford and Yurukoglu (2012), which provides more detail about the industry’s
structure. There was some vertical integration during our sample period: News Cor-
poration had a controlling interest in DirecTV, and Time Warner and Time Warner
Cable were integrated.
The foci of this study are the cable news channels CNN, the Fox News Channel,
and MSNBC. CNN began broadcasting in 1980 as one of the earliest cable channels of
any genre, and pioneered the 24 hour news channel format. It was acquired by Time
Warner in 1996. CNN does not have any explicit ideological orientation.
9
The Fox
News Channel and MSNBC both entered the market in the mid 1990’s. Launched
by the News Corporation in late 1996, Fox News Channel’s business strategy was to
provide news with a more conservative slant. This strategy and the perception of such
a slant continues today. Fox News has become one of the most highly rated cable
channels across all genres. It is a cultural force in the U.S. synonymous with media
bias and the mixing of news and entertainment. MSNBC began as a joint venture
between NBC and Microsoft. At the outset, MSNBC did not have any explicit slant.
MSNBC changed its business strategy in the mid-2000’s to provide news with a more
liberal slant (Sanneh, 2013).
The channel lineup, or the numerical ordering of channels, varies by local cable
system. In most cases the first ten to twenty channel positions are allocated to the
over-the-air broadcast affiliates. For example, NBC4 occupies channel position 4 in
Washington D.C. area cable systems. After the over-the-air channels, the cable chan-
9
In our analyses we make no assumption that CNN’s content is neutral or moderate, and treat it symmet-
rically with MSNBC and Fox. We apply the same text-based measures to estimate its ideology, and flexibly
estimate its effect on viewers’ political preferences.
7
nels begin. We assert in this paper that the ordering of a channel in the lineup can
have significant effects on the viewership of news channels.
10
The obvious empirical concern is that a channel might be placed in lower positions
in localities with high tastes for the channel. We later examine that concern with a
placebo test of whether satellite subscriber viewership is correlated with local cable
channel positions. Describing the process by which channel positions were determined
provides additional support for the claim that channel positions are valid instruments.
The 1994-2001 period during which Fox News and MSNBC were rolling out was
a tumultuous time for the cable television industry. This period saw many systems
upgrade from older analog to newer digital equipment, expanding the number of chan-
nels cable operators were able to offer their subscribers. Coincident with this technical
advance, a wave of new channels (including the two cable news channels that are the
focus of this paper) entered cable lineups alongside first-generation channels like CNN,
ESPN, MTV, TBS, TNT and the USA Network.
However, the timing of the advances in content and technology were not coordi-
nated: some systems invested in upgrades early, before the wave of new channel entry,
and some later. Meanwhile, bilateral deals for content distribution were being struck
between the numerous new channels and cable system operators, of which in this period
before the early-2000s wave of consolidation there were many. As a result, the channel
positioning that Fox or MSNBC ended up with on a given local system depended on
the specific timing of that system’s negotiations with multiple new channels as well as
its decision of when to upgrade. Channels were often allocated positions sequentially,
in the order in which they were added to a system.
11
Combined with the key principle
in lineup design of limiting the changes in channel positions as much as possible so as
to not confuse existing customers, these chaotic historical factors generated persistent
cross-system variation in the positioning of Fox News and MSNBC.
12
Figure 1 plots the growth in subscribers for a group of peer channels during this
10
The significant relationship between channel position and viewership holds for all genres, not just news.
11
In Appendix C, we show that channel positions correlate with the best available position in the year
before a channel was added.
12
Some systems have shuffled positions over time as channels went out of business, as channel capacity
expanded and as new channels came online. Some local managers pursued a strategy of moving channels
with similar content or in the same genre together into “neighborhoods,” when possible. In general, however,
the ordering of cable channels is highly persistent from year to year.
8
time period. The top line shows ESPN, which was available on virtually every cable
system. The other channels in the graph all experienced substantial growth during this
time period. Idiosyncracies in the timing of contracts and system upgrades created
variation in channel positions for a given channel across locations. In some cases, if
Fox News was being added to a system facing capacity constraints, its channel position
was determined by the position of the channel it was replacing. On systems owned by
the multiple-system operator TCI in 1996, Fox News was reported to have replaced one
of as many as twelve different channels depending on the location (Dempsey (1996)).
0 20 40 60 80
National Subscribers (M)
1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
Year
Animal Planet BET Bravo
Cartoon Network Comedy Central E! Entertainment TV
ESPN ESPN 2 FX
Food Network Fox News Channel History Channel
MSNBC SyFy, Sci−Fi truTV, Court TV
Figure 1: Number of subscribers for a group of peer channels by year for the period 1994-
2001. National subscriber numbers according to SNL Kagan data.
9
3 Data
We use seven categories of data sets: (1) Nielsen FOCUS data on cable channel lineups
by zip code by year, (2) the National Annenberg Election Survey (NAES) and the
Cooperative Congressional Election Study (CCES, Ansolabehere (2011)) on individual
demographics, zip code, and intent to vote Republican in 2000, 2004, and 2008 U.S.
Presidential elections, (3) Mediamark and Simmons individual survey data on hours
spent watching cable news by channel, individual demographics, and zip code, (4)
County level presidential election vote share data compiled by Congressional Quarterly,
(5) U.S. Census demographics by zip code, (6) Broadcast transcripts of cable news from
Lexis-Nexis, and (7) the Congressional Record. We now describe each data set and
exposit several empirical relationships that are central to our results. Most of our
analysis focuses on the years 2000 to 2008, but some data sets cover through 2011.
3.1 Cable Lineups: Nielsen FOCUS
The Nielsen FOCUS database consists of yearly observations on cable systems. The
key variables in this data set are, for each system and year, the availability of CNN,
Fox News, and MSNBC, the channel positions of CNN, Fox News, and MSNBC, when
available, and the zip codes served by the system. In Figure 2, we document the
availability of each of these news channels by year. CNN was already near-universal
by 1998. Fox News and MSNBC became widespread over the sample period. Table
1 presents the mean and standard deviation of channel position for each of the three
news channel by year. CNN is generally lower than Fox, which is generally lower than
MSNBC. The pairwise correlations in positions of the channels are around .3, with
variation depending on the channel pair and the year. As seen in Figure 4, Fox News
Channel is in a lower position than CNN in 11% of the observations when both are
available. MSNBC is in a lower position than CNN in 7% of the observations, and in a
lower position than Fox News Channel in 23% of the observations. Table 2 shows the
corresponding Republican vote shares and cable news viewership levels conditional on
lowest ordered channel. The average Republican vote share is higher and the average
hours of Fox News watched are higher when Fox News is in the lowest position.
There are two important facts about this data set. First, the Nielsen FOCUS
database contains the universe of cable systems. Second, all entries are updated on a
10
regular basis. This feature is different from the Cable and Television Factbook used in
previous studies. We detail this important difference in Appendix A.
Figure 2: Availability of cable news channels by year. The solid lines represent the fraction
of cable subscribers for whom the news channel was carried on their system. The dashed
lines represent the fraction of cable systems which carry the news channels. By 2002, nearly
all cable subscribers had access to Fox News and MSNBC.
3.2 Individual Voting Data: NAES and CCES
The National Annenberg Election Study (NAES) is a large-scale phone survey con-
ducted each presidential election cycle which asks individual respondents a range of
political preference questions, along with demographic identifiers. We use data from
the 2000, 2004, and 2008 election cycles, including the confidential zip-code field. The
key variables are demographic variables such as race, age, and income; zip code; stated
ideology; and actual or intent to vote in the current presidential election. The NAES
surveys were conducted on a rolling basis over the course of each election, with most
11
Year CNN FNC MSNBC
Mean SD Mean SD Mean SD
2000 17.34 10.49 35.40 12.94 39.00 12.76
2004 21.83 12.83 38.22 14.31 41.66 13.53
2008 24.67 14.40 37.48 14.42 42.87 18.18
All 21.14 13.06 37.28 14.17 41.59 15.68
Table 1: Mean and standard deviation of channel position by news channel by year in election
years.
0 .01 .02 .03 .04
Density
0 25 50 75 100 125 150
Channel Position
CNN
Fox News
MSNBC
Figure 3: Kernel Density Estimate of Distribution of Channel Positions by Channel
12
Figure 4: Fraction of systems with certain ordinal configurations.
CNN Lowest FNC Lowest MSNBC Lowest All
Republican Vote Share 0.5023 0.5082 0.4900 0.5017
Fox Hours Watched 1.0556 1.1440 1.0608 1.0699
CNN Hours Watched 1.2078 1.2657 1.2471 1.2222
MSNBC Hours Watched 0.5219 0.5279 0.5690 0.5294
Table 2: Mean Republican presidential vote shares and cable news hours watched by lowest
ordered cable news channel.
respondents contacted before election day but some after. We combine actual vote
(from respondents contacted after election day) together with intent to vote (from
those contacted before) into a single variable.
The 2004 and 2008 NAES surveys also asked respondents to report their “most
watched” cable news source, if any. We use this variable in estimating OLS regressions
of vote intention on channel viewership.
These data are summarized in Table 3. For 2008, we add data from the Cooperative
Congressional Election Study (CCES) on the same variables that we use from the
NAES.
13
3.3 Individual Viewership Data: Mediamark and Sim-
mons
Mediamark and Simmons are two commercial data vendors who survey individuals on
their usage of different brands, including media usage. We use Mediamark for 2000
to 2007, and Simmons for 2008 to 2011. The key variables for our study are year, zip
code, individual demographics, whether the respondent subscribes to cable, satellite,
or neither, and the reported number of hours watched per week of CNN, Fox News
Channel, and MSNBC. These data are also summarized in Table 3.
3.4 County Level Vote Shares and Census
We use county level presidential vote shares for the Presidential elections in 2000, 2004,
and 2008 obtained from the Voting and Elections Collection Database maintained by
Congressional Quarterly. We also use zip code level demographic statistics from the
2000 and 2010 US Census. We use these data to construct county-level distributions
of household income, age, race, education, and initial ideology, from which we draw a
set of simulated consumer-voters for the model of section 5. For zip codes which span
multiple counties, we split the zip code across the relevant counties in proportion to
the county size.
3.5 Broadcast Transcripts and Congressional Record
To quantify the slant of each news channel in each year, we follow Gentzkow and
Shapiro (2010)
13
in comparing the language that the channels use to language that
Congresspeople use. We modify their statistical procedure as well as create scores for
each channel for each year. This procedure does not recognize irony, satire, sub-text,
nor tone, and thus likely underestimates the true dispersion in slant as the slanted
outlets sometimes employ the language of the other side of political spectrum for pur-
poses of mockery or derision.
14
We obtained broadcast transcripts for CNN, Fox News
13
The idea is similar in spirit to Groseclose and Milyo (2005)
14
This is one reason why we exclude Comedy Central, which features two prominent slanted cable news
programs, The Daily Show with Jon Stewart and The Colbert Report, from the analysis. Their slant relies
heavily on satire and is not as reasonably quantified based on phrase usage. As a separate matter, Comedy
Central has other highly viewed shows which are not explicitly political such as South Park, and our data
14
N Mean SD
NAES/CCES
Male 122243 0.460 0.498
White 122243 0.841 0.365
Black 122243 0.082 0.275
Hispanic 122243 0.067 0.251
Age 122243 47.801 16.071
College Graduate 122243 0.369 0.482
Household Income ($000s) 122243 65.312 50.796
Intent to Vote: Republican 122243 0.498 0.500
Self Reported Ideology 119524 3.185 1.042
Mediamark/Simmons
Male 209352 0.505 53.130
White 209352 0.812 15.738
Black 209352 0.106 0.390
Hispanic 209352 0.109 0.308
Age 209352 46.314 0.312
College Graduate 209352 0.328 0.475
Household Income ($000s) 209352 70.744 0.303
Cable Subscriber 209352 0.656 0.261
DirecTV Subscriber 209352 0.102 0.469
Dish Network Subscriber 209352 0.074 0.500
Watch any CNN 209352 0.360 0.480
CNN Hours per Week 209352 1.223 2.816
Watch any Fox News Channel 209352 0.291 0.454
Fox News Channel Hours per Week 209352 1.070 2.847
Watch any MSNBC 209352 0.203 0.402
MSNBC Hours per Week 209352 0.529 1.726
Table 3: Summary Statistics for individual level NAES/CCES and Mediamark/Simmons
data. Ideology ranges from Very Liberal (1) to Very Conservative (5). The variables except-
ing age, household income, and the hours per week are dummy variables.
15
Channel, and MSNBC from the Lexis-Nexis database for the sample period 1998-2012
by downloading all transcripts per year for each identifiable cable news program from
each of the three channels.
Taking the Congressional Record for each year, the first steps are to stem the
words, remove stop words, and then count the frequency of usage of two word phrases
by each Congress person. Each Congress person has a measure of their ideology, the
DW-NOMINATE score from McCarty et al. (1997), which places them on the interval
[1, 1] with more positive being more conservative. The second step is to correlate
phrase usage with the DW-Nominate score. There are many more two word phrases
than Congresspeople, and an ordinary least squares criterion is therefore useless because
there are more variables than observations. For each year, we run an Elastic Net (Zou
and Hastie, 2005) regression of DW Nominate score of frequency of phrase usage where
an observation is a Congressperson. The Elastic Net regression is a variable selection
algorithm that combines the LASSO and the Ridge Regression regularization penalties.
In Table 4, we follow Gentzkow and Shapiro (2010) in showing a subset of the most
indicative partisan phrases selected by the Elastic Net regression for 2000, 2004, and
2008.
We use the estimated coefficients to predict the DW-Nominate score for each cable
news channel in each year. We then apply a three period moving average smoothing
filter. The results of this procedure are in Figure 5. Fox News is consistently more
conservative than the other two channels. MSNBC switches to being more liberal in
the mid-2000’s. The estimates also reveal increased polarization of cable news over
time. The text based measures produce estimated ideologies for the channels that are
more moderate than the median members of each party. In the modelling to come, we
allow for consumers to perceive these news channels to be more or less ideologically
differentiated, in proportion to these estimates. Indeed, our estimates for this scale
factor put Fox News Channel very close to the median Republican voter.
are aggregated to the channel level.
16
Figure 5: Estimated Ideology by Channel-Year
17
2000 Party 2004 Party 2008 Party
60 minut R 17 month D 11 countri R
administr fail R administr continu D allow vote R
american coupl R administr fail D american resourc R
bank credit D administr refus D approv rate R
benefit wealthiest D administr republican D bring skyrocket R
big bank D administr want D bush chenei D
break wealthi D american without D bush took D
break wealthiest D bid contract D busi come D
bush tax D billion iraq D busi todai D
busi come R bipartisan commiss D call abort R
caught nap R bush budget D can produc R
child tax R busi come R capit gain R
continu everi D civil justic R control two D
coupl pai R compani hmo D cost energi R
cut wealthi D corpor profit D dai spent R
cut wealthiest D cost energi R death tax R
eight billion R cost war D deep sea R
elderli peopl D cut wealthi D deep water R
elimin death R cut wealthiest D democrat bill R
feder bureaucraci R date time R democrat colleagu R
follow morn R don nickl R develop resourc R
gun hand D econom advis D entitl reform R
hard earn R evil empir R explor oil R
huge tax D fall far D kill littl R
increas domest R far short D liquid fuel R
labor right D gdp growth R major parti R
largest tax R govern regul R minimum wage D
larg tax D govern spend R never express R
line vote D hold line R new nuclear R
live poverti D increas medicar D new refineri R
modern school D invas iraq D nuclear plant R
monei washington R job administr D pelosi said R
name peopl D largest deficit D plan bring R
need prescript D lawrenc v R process law R
pai social R liabil cost R produc american R
per child R major want D product american R
pm todai R marriag licens R properti without R
presid busi R marriag will R record profit D
reduc tax R mass grave R refineri capac R
reproduct health D medicar premium D remind realli R
republican bill D million manufactur D safe wai R
republican friend D presid aristid D sign petit R
republican propos D presid econom D soon on R
right organ D print report R sue opec R
riski scheme R protect tradit R suppli energi R
sensibl gun D reserv us R tax american R
seven million R revenu feder R tax burden R
sinc columbin D reward compani D tax hike R
state arizona R sector job D tax oil R
still republican D servic author R thing common R
tax death R ship job D took offic D
tax hike R social justic D trillion barrel R
tax just R time administr D trillion cubic R
unidentifi male D trillion surplu D unfund liabil R
us later R univers health D v wade R
wealthiest american D war cost D warrantless surveil D
wealthiest peopl D wealthiest american D wast spend R
work condit D woman right D without due R
year administr D yet todai R
Table 4: Top decile of partisan indicative phrases selected by Elastic Net for years 2000,
2004, and 2008. Word variants are stemmed to their roots.
18
4 Regression Analysis
This section provides the regression results on the relationship between channels po-
sitions, watching Fox News and MSNBC, and voting Republican. These results serve
as the basis for the model estimation and simulation in the following sections. The re-
sults in this section do not depend on the behavioral model estimation that we specify
in Section 5. This section can be read and evaluated as a stand-alone instrumental
variables regression analysis.
The first stage regressions are channel viewership against channel positions, chan-
nel availability, year effects, and demographics. The second stage regression is intent
to vote Republican against predicted viewership, channel availability, year effects, and
demographics.
15
We present the placebo first stage regression of channel viewership
by satellite subscribers against cable channel positions, cable channel availability, year
effects, and demographics.
16
We also present the OLS regression of intent to vote
Republican against channel viewership, channel availability, year effects, and demo-
graphics because the OLS regression is also relevant for the model estimation.
4.1 Viewership on Channel Positions: First Stage with
Individual Level Data
The first stage describes how hours watched varies with channel position. We use
channel-year fixed effects to ask whether a given channel has more viewership when it
is in a lower position. The idea is that lower channel positions induce more viewership
for channels such as Fox News and MSNBC because the higher watched content tends
to be in lower channel positions for historical reasons.
17
The most obvious mechanism
to generate such an effect is a costly search model. Consider a viewer who just finished
watching a television program, and begins to search for a new program. Their search
will begin from the channel they were watching, which is likely to be in a low position.
15
The variation in viewership attributable to differential availability of Fox News and MSNBC is thus not
part of the estimation strategy.
16
This serves to argue the validity of channel positions as instrumental variables because if channel positions
were tailored to local tastes, they should correlate with viewership of satellite subscribers in the same zip
code.
17
In addition to the broadcast networks ABC, CBS, Fox, and NBC, the lower channel positions are occupied
by the earliest entrants into cable (eg ESPN, MTV, TNT, USA) which also have high viewership.
19
They will move away from that channel, thereby making it more likely they stop nearer
to that channel than further away.
18
The obvious worry is that channel positions are
tailored to local tastes so that channels which will be watched more often are easier to
find. We address this concern with a placebo test that shows that local cable positions
do not correlate with viewership by satellite subscribers in the same zip code.
There are two regressions for each channel to model explicitly the mass of consumers
who watch zero hours of a given news channel, which is a salient feature of the data.
The median individual hours watched for each news channel is zero. One regression
for each channel is a linear probability model for whether one watches the channel at
all, or not. The second regression for each channel is for how long one watches the
channel, conditional on watching at all.
h
c
it
= δ
ct
+ a
it
+ η
c
x
it
+ θ
c,CNN
p
CNN
it
+ θ
c,F NC
p
F NC
it
+ θ
c,MSN BC
p
MSN BC
it
+ e
ict
χ
c
it
=
˜
δ
ct
+ ˜a
it
+ ˜η
c
x
it
+
˜
θ
c,CNN
p
CNN
it
+
˜
θ
c,F NC
p
F NC
it
+
˜
θ
c,MSN BC
p
MSN BC
it
+ ˜e
ict
where p
j
it
is the logged channel position of j in individual i’s zip code in year t, δ
ct
and
˜
δ
ct
are channel-year fixed effects, x
it
are individual level demographics, and a
it
and
˜a
it
are fixed effects for availability of the cable news channels to individual i. We choose
a log functional form for the position effects on the basis of the empirical relationship
between position and viewership. Figure 6 shows the relationship in the full set of
96 channels measured by MediaMark. We first regress hours watched on demographic
attributes of the respondents plus fixed effects for each channel and each year in the
dataset, and plot the residual hours watched against ordinal channel position. The
resulting relationship is negative, with a slope that steadily diminishes as channel
position increases.
To simplify the presentation, we present in Table 5 first stage estimates for re-
gressions of hours watched on channel positions without modeling the mass of zero
viewership.
19
Own channel position has the expected sign and is strongly statistically
18
Bias to the top of a list or default option in search is documented in eye tracking studies for yellow pages
(Lohse (1997)) and survey response (Galesic et al. (2008)). There is a theoretical literature in economics
modelling such behavior (see Rubinstein and Salant (2006), Horan (2010), Masatlioglu and Nakajima (2013),
and the literature on status-quo bias more generally.)
19
For the 2SLS estimates, we model the first stage as the combination of a linear probability model of
20
−0.25
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
0 50 100 150
Ordinal Channel Position
Residual Ratings (Hours)
Figure 6: Residual hours watched (after removing individual demographic effects plus chan-
nel and year fixed effects) of all 96 channels in the MediaMark dataset, plotted against the
channel’s ordinal position in the lineup.
21
(1) (2) (3)
VARIABLES Fox News Hours CNN Hours MSNBC Hours
log(Fox News Position) -0.122*** -0.0309 0.0499***
(0.0212) (0.0215) (0.0134)
log(CNN Position) -0.0106 -0.111*** -0.0148*
(0.0136) (0.0138) (0.00859)
log(MSNBC Position) 0.128*** 0.0721*** -0.0969***
(0.0230) (0.0233) (0.0145)
HH Income 0.0116*** 0.00677*** 0.00535***
(0.00134) (0.00137) (0.000847)
HH Income
2
-0.000110*** -4.86e-05*** -4.23e-05***
(1.41e-05) (1.43e-05) (8.87e-06)
HH Income
3
2.86e-07*** 1.22e-07*** 1.08e-07***
(4.04e-08) (4.10e-08) (2.54e-08)
Age -0.00282 -0.0137*** 0.00229
(0.00357) (0.00363) (0.00225)
Age
2
0.000340*** 0.000531*** 8.20e-05***
(3.76e-05) (3.82e-05) (2.37e-05)
White 0.175*** -0.329*** -0.0981***
(0.0336) (0.0341) (0.0212)
Black 0.268*** 0.0934** 0.0231
(0.0416) (0.0423) (0.0262)
Hispanic -0.256*** -0.184*** -0.0997***
(0.0301) (0.0306) (0.0190)
College -0.124*** 0.287*** 0.113***
(0.0186) (0.0189) (0.0117)
Male 0.245*** 0.192*** 0.120***
(0.0165) (0.0168) (0.0104)
log(N Channels) -0.0155 -0.0815** 0.0328
(0.0327) (0.0332) (0.0206)
Observations 137,312 137,312 137,312
R-squared 0.037 0.040 0.013
Year FE Yes Yes Yes
F-test for Positions 16.33 23.61 18.14
Prob > F 1.32e-10 0 0
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 5: Three OLS Regressions of hours watched by channel on cable channel availability,
local cable channel positions interacted with availability, demographics, and year dummy
variables for the sample of cable subscribers. The F statistic is for the joint test that all
the coefficients on the channel positions interacted with availability are equal to zero.
22
(1) (2) (3)
VARIABLES Fox News Hours CNN Hours MSNBC Hours
log(Fox News Position) -0.0150 0.00411 0.0146
(0.0442) (0.0381) (0.0255)
log(CNN Position) -0.00219 0.0147 -0.00924
(0.0300) (0.0258) (0.0173)
log(MSNBC Position) 0.0220 -0.000588 -0.0201
(0.0480) (0.0413) (0.0276)
HH Income 0.00662** -0.000931 0.00233
(0.00264) (0.00227) (0.00152)
HH Income
2
-4.42e-05* 2.59e-05 -1.39e-05
(2.67e-05) (2.30e-05) (1.54e-05)
HH Income
3
9.92e-08 -8.23e-08 3.66e-08
(7.52e-08) (6.47e-08) (4.33e-08)
Age -0.0145* -0.00497 0.00737*
(0.00753) (0.00648) (0.00433)
Age
2
0.000581*** 0.000367*** 4.13e-05
(8.01e-05) (6.90e-05) (4.61e-05)
White 0.176*** -0.440*** -0.0566
(0.0601) (0.0518) (0.0346)
Black 0.138* 0.0452 0.126***
(0.0790) (0.0680) (0.0455)
Hispanic -0.353*** -0.144*** -0.0950***
(0.0559) (0.0481) (0.0322)
College -0.0138 0.312*** 0.0834***
(0.0391) (0.0337) (0.0225)
Male 0.210*** 0.197*** 0.116***
(0.0334) (0.0288) (0.0192)
log(N Channels) 0.0478 0.0196 0.0181
(0.0560) (0.0482) (0.0323)
Observations 36,735 36,735 36,735
R-squared 0.046 0.033 0.012
Year FE Yes Yes Yes
F-test for Positions 0.0863 0.124 0.331
Prob > F 0.968 0.946 0.803
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 6: Placebo Regressions: Three OLS Regressions of hours watched by channel on cable
channel availability, local cable channel positions interacted with local cable availability,
demographics, and year dummy variables for the sample of satellite subscribers. The F
statistic is for the joint test that all the coefficients on the channel positions interacted with
availability are equal to zero.
23
significantly different from zero for own hours watched. The magnitudes imply that
an improvement of the Fox News channel position from the 75th percentile to 25th
percentile would increase viewership by 4 minutes. The cross-channel position effects
are generally positive, reflecting substitution consistent with our viewership model.
20
The first stage F statistics on the instrumental variables range from 16.3 for the Fox
News Channel regression to 23.6 in the MSNBC regression.
As a placebo test for whether channel positions respond to unobserved character-
istics of the local population, we repeat the same regressions on the sample of satellite
subscribers but using the channel positions on the local cable system. If the channel
positions on the local cable system are chosen in response to unobservable local charac-
teristics, then these positions should predict satellite viewership. The results in Table 6
indicate that channel positions on the cable system do not predict viewership on satel-
lite. None of the coefficients on cable channel position are statistically distinguishable
from zero for satellite subscribers. These coefficients are always much closer to zero
than in the sample of cable subscribers. Finally, we can reject equality of nearly all of
them with the corresponding cable coefficients with high degrees of confidence.
21
Demographics predict viewership in similar manners for both cable and satellite
subscribers. Across locations, satellite subscriber characteristics correlate strongly with
cable subscriber characteristics. Table 7 shows the regression coefficients of mean
satellite subscriber characteristics on mean cable subscriber characteristics in the same
cable system territory, nearly all of which are positive and large. Since the means
of these characteristics are measured with sampling error - as they are constructed
watching the channel, and a linear regression of how much one watches conditional on watching. The 2SLS
coefficients have the same estimated magnitudes using either first stage model. The second stage Fox News is
only significant at the 90% level and the MSNBC effect drops just below conventional confidence levels when
we do not model the mass on zero explicitly, though the signs and magnitudes of the effects are the same.
The loss of precision is not surprising given that a linear model for viewership will grossly under-predict the
number of viewers who watch zero hours.
20
CNN’s channel position is negative, though imprecise, in the Fox News and MSNBC regressions. A
negative coefficient would suggest a complementarity between CNN and these two channels, whereas our
model does not admit such a complementarity. We note this as a weakness of the analysis. Modelling the
complementarity in the model we use is difficult computationally as the first stage optimization would have
to be solved numerically rather than with an analytical solution that our current demand system admits.
21
In the Appendix, we carry out Chow tests assuming the demographic effects on viewership are the same
between cable and satellite subscribers, and formally reject that the cable position effect on cable subscribers
is equal to the effect on satellite subscribers.
24
from the television viewership survey samples - the OLS coefficients are attenuated.
In the table, we address this measurement error problem in two ways.
22
First, we
progressively restrict the regression to markets with more and more survey respondents
as these markets will have less sampling error. Second, we instrument for the mean
cable characteristic with lead and lagged mean cable characteristic. Survey respondents
are sampled independently from year to year. Consistent with measurement error, the
coefficients genereally tend upwards to one when we restrict to system-years with more
respondents. Furthermore, the IV coefficients are generally very close to one.
In the same vein, we can look directly at viewership patterns. Satellite viewers
watch 1.2 fewer minutes per week of Fox News Channel on average relative to cable
viewers (on an overall mean of 90 minutes). At the bottom of Table 7, we regress
predicted mean viewership of satellite subscribers (predicted from demographics) on
that of cable subscribers. We also regress the cable system territory mean residual
viewership of satellite subscribers (net of demographics) on the mean residual viewer-
ship of cable subscribers. Across the board, cable and satellite subscribers within the
same cable system territory display strong correlations of demographics and viewing
behavior.
What is important is that satellite subscribers’ ideologies are correlated with cable
subscribers’ ideologies. Given that all observable characteristics correlate positively,
and that demographics explain little of whether or not an individual is a satellite sub-
scriber, we find such a scenario to be plausible. Our principal identification assumption
is thus that cable channel positions are not chosen to reflect unobservable attributes
that are unique to cable subscribers’ (to the extent that they differ from satellite sub-
scribers’) political leanings in a locality. The placebo tests provide empirical evidence
in favor of this assumption.
4.2 Voting on Projected Viewership: 2SLS with Individ-
ual Level Data
Let y
it
be an indicator for whether individual i intends to vote for the Republican
Presidential candidate in the election of year t. Let h
j
it
be the reported hours watched
22
One could also dis-attenuate the coefficients as the variance induced by sampling is known. This exercise
is complicated because each cable system-year has different sampling variance.
25
Characteristic N>0 N>10 N>50 N>100 IV
Black 0.581*** 0.708*** 0.783*** 0.912*** 0.996***
(0.0129) (0.0148) (0.0279) (0.0571) (0.0388)
College 0.398*** 0.540*** 0.705*** 0.716*** 0.917***
(0.0165) (0.0202) (0.0412) (0.0714) (0.0779)
HH Income 0.498*** 0.612*** 0.820*** 0.886*** 0.973***
(0.0144) (0.0166) (0.0309) (0.0607) (0.0637)
Age 0.261*** 0.358*** 0.395*** 0.490*** 0.791***
(0.0165) (0.0212) (0.0458) (0.0764) (0.0998)
Hispanic 0.538*** 0.665*** 0.778*** 0.843*** 0.838***
(0.0138) (0.0159) (0.0234) (0.0345) (0.0304)
Party ID R 0.105*** 0.289*** 0.629*** 0.888*** 1.552***
(0.0286) (0.0503) (0.106) (0.172) (0.437)
Party ID D 0.118*** 0.228*** 0.630*** 1.174*** 2.947*
(0.0282) (0.0506) (0.117) (0.211) (1.690)
Predicted Fox News 0.766*** 0.804*** 0.912*** 0.924*** 0.965***
(0.0130) (0.0137) (0.0215) (0.0274) (0.0453)
Predicted CNN Viewing 0.506*** 0.556*** 0.633*** 0.720*** 0.831***
(0.0177) (0.0198) (0.0361) (0.0523) (0.146)
Predicted MSNBC Viewing 0.766*** 0.791*** 0.831*** 0.810*** 0.828***
(0.0132) (0.0141) (0.0259) (0.0397) (0.0761)
Fox News Residual 0.111*** 0.168*** 0.453*** 0.376*** 0.612**
(0.0237) (0.0282) (0.0624) (0.0862) (0.304)
CNN Residual 0.180*** 0.190*** 0.272*** 0.340*** 0.645***
(0.0191) (0.0201) (0.0452) (0.0656) (0.196)
MSNBC Residual 0.101*** 0.107*** 0.424*** 0.642*** 0.588**
(0.0210) (0.0221) (0.0613) (0.106) (0.246)
Note: The first column of coefficients uses all cable system territory-years. These coefficients
are attenuated because the mean cable is constructed from samples of survey respondents
which can be as few as 2 per cable system territory-year. The second column of coefficients
restricts to those with more than ten surveyed respondents. The third column of coefficients
restricts to those with more than fifty survey respondents. The fourth column of coefficients
restricts to those with more than 100 survey respondents. The final column of coefficients
are uses lead and lagged means of cable subscribers as instrumental variables as respondents
are sampled independently from year to year.
Table 7: Regression coefficients of demographic characteristics and cable news viewership of
satellite subscribers on the characteristics of cable subscribers in the same cable territory-year
in MediaMark / Simmons viewership data.
26
per week of channel j where j c, f, m with c corresponding to CNN, f to Fox News,
and m to MSNBC. We are interested in the coefficients in the population relationship:
y
it
= γ
t
+ a
it
+ αx
it
+ β
c
h
c
it
+ β
f
h
f
it
+ β
m
h
m
it
+
it
(1)
where γ are election fixed effects and α are election-specific coefficients on demo-
graphics x
i
. The assumption that is uncorrelated with the vector of hours watched
is untenable if consumers have a preference for like-minded news. We use channel po-
sitions as instrumental variables for these three endogenous variables, and estimate by
2SLS. Results from the second stage regressions are in Table 8. We compute standard
errors by bootstrap as deemed appropriate in two-sample IV settings by Inoue and
Solon (2010). Our estimates imply that being induced to watch an additional hour per
week of Fox News by the channel position instruments would lead to an approximately
14-point increase in the probability of voting Republican in presidential elections for
those induced into watching by the instrument.
23
In terms of magnitudes, the estimated effect of one hour of Fox News is just under
one-half of the effect of being black on voting Republican, and about equal to the
difference in dummy coefficients for residence in Ohio versus residence in Massachusetts.
We point out a few caveats regarding this seemingly large magnitude. First, the implied
effect on an election of removing Fox News will be significantly smaller, as the majority
of people do not watch any Fox News, and among those who do, the majority are
already going to vote Republican.
24
Second, our survey-based vote intention measure
may include individuals who are both unlikely to vote and lack an established political
ideology, and thus are more open to persuasion by slanted news.
25
When we restrict
our second stage to registered voters, the Fox News Channel coefficient falls to 0.107.
Enikolopov et al. (2011) examined both individual level survey data and actual vote
23
The typical change in viewership induced by the instrument is significantly less than one hour per week.
Given our first-stage estimates and the distribution of the instrument presented in Figure 3, a one-standard
deviation increase in channel position induces a roughly 3-minute-per-week increase in Fox News viewing.
24
In Section 7, we estimate a 1.3% change in the 2000 presidential election’s Republican vote share resulting
from the existence of Fox News. This estimate accounts for selective viewership.
25
An extensive literature on turnout in political science, e.g. Leighley and Nagler (2013), has found non-
voters to be much more likely to report independent partisan affiliation and “moderate” ideological leanings
than are regular voters.
27
(1)
VARIABLES Intent to Vote R
Fox News Channel Hours 0.137***
(0.0108)
CNN Hours 0.0221
(0.0197)
MSNBC Hours -0.101***
(0.0221)
HH Income 0.00273***
(0.000286)
HH Income
2
-2.22e-05***
(3.04e-06)
HH Income
3
5.65e-08***
(9.06e-09)
Age 0.00377***
(0.000620)
Age
2
-7.47e-05***
(9.25e-06)
White 0.0745***
(0.00740)
Black -0.357***
(0.00755)
Hispanic -0.0571***
(0.00606)
College -0.0636***
(0.00556)
Male 0.0516***
(0.00339)
log(N Channels) -0.0975***
(0.00463)
Observations 122,243
R-squared 0.089
Year Effects Yes
Channel Availability Yes
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 8: Second Stage regressions of NAES and CCES intent to vote Republican vote share
on predicted hours watched from the first stage.
28
shares and found significantly larger effects of media consumption using the individual
level survey data. Finally, as the behavioral model makes clear, we are estimating a
single coefficient in a world of heterogenous treatment effects. The IV estimates reflect
an average treatment effect on individuals induced into watching by the instrument.
These viewers will lack strong political orientations, and thus be more malleable.
There is additional validation when we interact the instrumented time watched
with election year dummy variables. The Fox News effect increases over time. The
MSNBC effect is only present in 2008, after MSNBC made the switch to liberal slanted
programming. These interaction terms are both consistent with the ideology estimates
in Figure 5. First, the estimated ideology of Fox News moves further to the right over
the sample period. Second, MSNBC’s persuasive effect only dips to the left after the
2004 election. Sorting out the dynamics of persuasion implied by these results are an
interesting angle for future research.
4.3 Voting on Viewership: OLS with Individual Level
Data
We also present the estimated coefficients in an OLS regression of intent to vote Re-
publican on demographics and indicators for most watched cable news channel in the
NAES data. This is the OLS analog to the second stage above with two slight differ-
ences. First, it uses only indicators for most watched cable news channel rather than
hours watched. Second, the sample is restricted to NAES data. The reason for these
differences is because the OLS regression is only possible on the NAES data where
hours watched is not available. In the 2SLS, we estimate the first stage on Mediamark
and Simmons data,
26
and use the estimated coefficients to predict hours watched on
the NAES and CCES data which has intent to vote.
The purpose of presenting the mis-specified OLS regression is because we use it
in the model estimation later to estimate the taste for like-minded news. Imagine a
researcher who purports to estimate the influence of Fox News on voting Republican by
regressing intent to vote Republican on an indicator for whether Fox News is the most
watched news channel. Such an estimate would lack credibility because it mixes any
influence effect with the selection into viewership of Fox News by those who intend to
26
Mediamark and Simmons data do not include Intent to vote.
29
(1)
VARIABLES Intent to Vote R
Fox News Channel Hours * Year 2000 0.100***
(0.0304)
Fox News Channel Hours * Year 2004 0.122***
(0.0204)
Fox News Channel Hours * Year 2008 0.141***
(0.0154)
CNN Hours * Year 2000 0.0148
(0.0253)
CNN Hours * Year 2004 -0.0105
(0.0258)
CNN Hours * Year 2008 0.0337
(0.0205)
MSNBC Hours * Year 2000 0.0296
(0.0416)
MSNBC Hours * Year 2004 -0.0144
(0.0470)
MSNBC Hours * Year 2008 -0.113***
(0.0226)
HH Income 0.00246***
(0.000450)
HH Income
2
-1.99e-05***
(4.10e-06)
HH Income
3
5.03e-08***
(1.14e-08)
Age 0.00328***
(0.000636)
Age
2
-6.87e-05***
(1.02e-05)
White 0.0754***
(0.00841)
Black -0.358***
(0.00864)
Hispanic -0.0574***
(0.00671)
College -0.0681***
(0.00646)
Male 0.0497***
(0.00512)
log(N Channels) -0.0964***
(0.00468)
Observations 122,243
R-squared 0.090
Year Effects Yes
Channel Availability Yes
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 9: Second Stage regressions of NAES and CCES intent to vote Republican vote share
on predicted hours watched from the first stage interacted with election year effects.
30
vote Republican because of tastes for like-minded news. Our approach is to use channel
positions to estimate the influence effect, while jointly matching the OLS coefficient to
estimate the tastes for like minded news.
Table 10 confirms a positive correlation between intending to vote Republican and
indicating that one’s most watched cable news channel is Fox News, and corresponding
negative coefficients for indicating MSNBC and CNN.
5 Model
The model for a given election cycle has two stages. In the first stage, the consumer-
voters choose a television package and how much time to watch the cable news channels.
In the second stage, the consumer-voters vote in the Presidential election. Between
the first and second stage, the consumer-voters’ ideologies evolve as a function of the
ideologies of and time spent watching the news channels.
5.1 Voter Ideology and Presidential Vote Decision
Our consumer-voters have a latent unidimensional political ideology which determines
their vote choice in presidential elections. We denote the left-right ideology of consumer-
voter i by r
it
.
We specify voters’ initial ideologies as a function of their county of residence. Specif-
ically, we estimate a logit model of vote choice with county dummies as explanatory
variables, which matches county level vote shares from the previous election cycle.
27
The county-level intercepts from this model then determine the simulated consumers’
initial ideologies, along with an iid logit error term:
r
ij0
= δ
j
+
ij
(2)
Where δ
j
is the estimated county intercept for county j, consumer i’s county of
residence. From this starting point, ideology may evolve if the consumer watches cable
news, according to a process described in detail later in this section.
27
E.g., simulated voters in the 2008 election cycle have their ideologies initialized using coefficients that
match county-level vote shares in the 2004 election.
31
(1)
VARIABLES Intent to Vote R
Most Watched CNN -0.0869***
(0.00633)
Most Watched Fox News Channel 0.329***
(0.00654)
Most Watched MSNBC -0.0963***
(0.00844)
HH Income 0.00427***
(0.000408)
HH Income
2
-3.11e-05***
(4.62e-06)
HH Income
3
7.21e-08***
(1.38e-08)
Age 0.00333***
(0.000759)
Age
2
-3.47e-05***
(7.38e-06)
White 0.103***
(0.00876)
Black -0.285***
(0.0111)
Hispanic -0.0909***
(0.00908)
College -0.0556***
(0.00465)
Male 0.0447***
(0.00423)
log(N Channels) -0.104***
(0.00786)
Observations 44,472
R-squared 0.230
Year Effects Yes
Channel Availability Yes
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 10: OLS linear probability regression of intent to vote Republican on demographics
and indicators for most watched cable news channel.
32
At election time, each voter votes for the party whose candidate’s announced po-
sition is closest to her own. This behavior is consistent with voting given a utility
function over the ideology of the winning candidate that is single-peaked with maxi-
mum at r
it
. As in all such spatial models, only the cutpoint between the candidate
positions, and not the absolute values of the positions, determine the voting decision.
We can, therefore, describe each presidential election using a single parameter P
t
, for
t {2000, 2004, 2008}. All voters to the left of the cutpoint (with r
it
< P
t
) vote for the
Democratic candidate in the election, and those to the right vote for the Republican.
5.2 Viewership and Subscription
The viewership time allocation and subscription portion of the model follows Crawford
and Yurukoglu (2012). Given access to the news channels C
jt
in package j in year
t, consumer-voter i allocates their time amongst watching those channels and other
activities to maximize:
v
ij
=
X
cC
jt
γ
ict
log(1 + T
ijc
) (3)
where γ
ict
is consumer-voter i’s preference parameter for news channel c in year
t. We choose the normalization that the outside option (doing anything other than
watching cable news) has γ
i0t
= 1 for all i, t, and parameterize the remaining vector of
γ
ict
as
γ
it
= χ
it
ν
it
χ
ict
Bernoulli(α
0ct
+ Π
0c
d
i
+ ζ
0
pos
ict
η((a + br
ct
) r
it
)
2
) (4)
ν
ict
Exp(α
ct
+ Π
c
d
i
+ ζpos
ict
) (5)
χ
ict
determines whether consumer-voter i has a non-zero preference for channel c.
28
It is a random function of demographics d
i
according to parameters Π
0
, a channel-
year specific fixed effect α
0ct
, the position of the channel in the lineup according to
28
We use this formulation because most consumers watch zero or one news channel.
33
ζ
0
, and the distance of consumer-voter i’s one dimensional political ideology r
it
from
the channel’s estimated ideology r
ct
according to η. This last term represents taste
for like-minded news and follows a similar parameterization to Gentzkow and Shapiro
(2010). The parameters a and b scale the text based ideology measures to allow for
consumers to perceive slant as a linear function of the text based slant measure. If
η is positive, then increasing the ideological distance between consumer-voter i and
channel c reduces the probability i watches c.
If the consumer-voter has a non-zero preference, the intensity of her preference is
drawn from an exponential distribution whose distributional parameter depends on
α
ct
, a channel-year specific fixed effect, demographics d
i
according to parameters Π,
and the position of the channel in the lineup according to ζ. The exponential shape
assumption mixed with a mass at zero is inspired by the raw data on hours watched
which features a mass at zero and right-skewed and monotonically decreasing density.
The constrained maximization problem defined by (3) has an analytic solution that
can be determined as follows. Define ρ
ict
as the Lagrange multipliers associated with
the non-negativity constraints on T
ict
. By complementary slackness, if ρ
ict
> 0 then
T
ict
= 0. From the first order condition, ρ
ict
= λ
it
γ
ict
where λ
it
is the Lagrange
multiplier on consumer i’s budget constraint. Therefore, T
ict
can be zero if and only if
γ
ict
< λ
it
.
For all the channels with γ
ict
> 0, λ
it
= γ
ict
/(1+ T
ict
). Additionally, each consumer
faces a time-budget constraint,
P
c
T
ict
= B, where B is the total time available (in our
scaling, the number of hours in a week: 168). This gives a system of equations with
solution:
λ
it
=
1 +
P
c
+
γ
ic
+
t
B + C
+
where c
+
are the indices of the channels that i watches a positive amount, and C
+
is the total number of such channels. Given this result, the iterative solution is to
replace the γ
ict
’s below the cutoff (1 +
P
c
γ
c
)/(B + C) with zero. If there were any
γ
ict
’s below this threshold, we now have a new cutoff defined by the remaining positive
γ
ict
’s, and we repeat the process again. There are at most C steps of this until we hit
the final set of positive γ
ict
’s, at which point we compute the times watched as:
34
T
ict
= (T + C
+
)
γ
ict
P
c
+
γ
ic
+
t
1(γ
ict
> 0)
The indirect utility from solving this problem enters into the consumer-voter’s de-
cision whether to subscribe to cable, satellite, or no television package at all. The
conditional indirect utility from subscribing to package j is
u
ij
= v
ij
+ δ
j
+
ij
where δ
j
is the mean utility of package j,
ij
is an idiosyncratic logit error term
and j corresponds to cable or satellite. We also allow consumers to subscribe to no
package at all. This choice is associated with a normalized δ
0
= 0 and, since we
assume consumers cannot watch cable news if they do not subscribe, the only choice is
to spend their entire time budget in non-cable-news activity. This yields corresponding
u
i0
= log(1 + B) +
i0
.
5.3 Ideological Influence
After watching cable news, consumer-voter i’s one-dimensional political ideology evolves
as a function of how much time i spends watching the news channels and the ideology
of the news channels.
29
We assume that i is attracted towards the ideologies of the
news channels he watches, the more so the more time i spends watching. Specifically
r
it
=
r
i,t1
+ ρ
P
c
T
ic,t1
(a + br
c,t1
)
1 + ρ
P
c
T
ic,t1
(6)
where r
i,t1
is i’s ideology prior to watching, r
it
is i’s new ideology, and ρ is a
parameter to be estimated which controls the magnitude of news channels’ influence
on viewers’ ideology. One interpretation of ρ is as a (per-hour) rate at which viewers
receive ideological signals while watching cable news. If voters treat signals from slanted
outlets as true draws on the state of the world, and further, if they do not account for
the lack of independence between repeated signals from the same source as in the model
29
The ideology measure is the same function of the text based slant measure that enters the viewership
decision problem.
35
of DeMarzo et al. (2003),
30
then equation (6) arises as the inverse-variance-weighted
average of signals observed by viewer i in period t.
31
The functional form here implies that a consumer-voter’s attraction is governed by
the same parameter (ρ), whether coming from the left or the right. This parameter
doesn’t depend on how far away the consumer-voter starts from the channel. It rules
out that a voter might watch a slanted channel, become disgusted, and move in the
opposite direction of the channel as in Arceneaux et al. (2012). Furthermore, consumer-
voters are naive about the influence effect when choosing time watched.
6 Estimation, Results, and Empirical Identifi-
cation
We estimate the parameters of the model by indirect inference (Smith (1990); Gourier-
oux et al. (1993)). This implies choosing the estimates of the model’s parameters to
match estimates of an auxiliary model. The auxiliary model consists of eight linear
regressions that fall into four categories, and a set of unconditional moments: (1) a
regression of individual level time spent watching each cable news channel on demo-
graphics and channel positions, conditional on watching the channel (three regressions),
(2) a linear probability regression of individual level watching any positive amount of
each cable news channel on demographics and channel positions (three regressions),
and (3) a linear probability regression of individual level intent to vote Republican on
demographics and predicted time spent watching from (1) and (2), and (4) an OLS
regression of intent to vote Republican on reporting whether Fox News, MSNBC, or
CNN is an individual’s most watched cable news channel. (1)-(3) correspond to a two-
stage least squares estimate of the effects of watching the cable news channels on voting
Republican using channel positions as instrumental variables. (4) corresponds to an
OLS regression of intent to vote Republican on viewership. Finally, we also match (5)
the actual vote shares in each presidential election, the year by year hours watched for
each channel, and the year by year fraction of non-zero viewership for each channel.
30
Gentzkow and Shapiro (2006) explore media consumption and endogenous slant with fully Bayesian
consumers.
31
For this interpretation to hold over a series of periods, we require that at the beginning of each period
the consumer gets an ideology shock which returns the variance of his ideology to 1.
36
We choose the model’s parameters so that estimating (1)-(5) on data simulated from
the model produce coefficient estimates with minimum distance to those in the data.
We weight the distance metric in proportion to the inverse of the standard errors in
the estimated relationships in the real data, with the exception that the IV and OLS
hours watched coefficients are weighted more heavily.
32
We also impose two constraints in our estimation procedure to accomodate the lin-
ear probability structure of equation 4. First, all the channel-year fixed effects in the
Bernoulli parameter (α
0ct
) are constrained to lie between zero and one. Second, the
demographic effects in the Bernoulli parameter
0c
) are constrained such that their
linear combination lies between -1 and 1 for all demographic types.
33
Note that these
constraints apply only to the fixed effects and the demographic parameters, and thus
do not prevent the model from setting the probability of a given individual watch-
ing a channel to be exactly zero, for example if the individual is very ideologically
distant from the channel or has the channel in very high position on her cable sys-
tem. We impose them to prevent the optimizer from moving into territory where the
channel-position and ideological effects have no influence on large numbers of simulated
individuals.
6.1 Empirical Identification
Empirical identification of the model’s parameters is relatively straightforward. In
terms of the notion of parameter estimated sensitivity, formalized in Gentzkow and
Shapiro (2013), ρ, the parameter which determines the degree of influence, is sensitive
to the coefficients on projected time in the second stage regression. η, the parameter
governing the degree of tastes for like-minded news, is sensitive to coefficients on which
channel is reported as most watched in the OLS regression relative to the coefficients
on projected hours watched in the second stage regressions. One intuition for these
estimates comes from considering the OLS regression of intent to vote Republican on
Fox News Channel hours watched. The coefficient estimates on hours watched of Fox
32
We begin with the inverse regression standard errors as our weights vector, but scale up the OLS and
IV hours watched weights by a relative factor of 100.
33
Our demographic variables are all either binary (such as our race and education dummies) or continuous
but bounded in the data (such as income and age). Hence, it is possible to define a demographic profile for
each channel with minimum and maximum viewership.
37
News Channel would not be a credible measure of the effects of consuming media
because the estimate would conflate tastes for like-minded news with any influence
effect. However, if one knew the level of the influence effect, then this estimate would
be informative about the tastes for like-minded news. Our approach is to measure the
influence effect by using channel positions as instrumental variables, and choose the
level of tastes for like minded news to explain the OLS coefficient conditional on the
influence effect.
ζ, the parameters determining the strength of channel positions in the time al-
location problem, are sensitive to the first stage coefficients on channel positions. A
similar straightforward relationship applies to the demographic factors influencing time
watched and the coefficients on demographics in the first stage regressions.
P
t
, the parameters characterizing the three presidential elections in our sample
period, are sensitive to the year-effects in the voting equations. These parameters
allow the model to capture national trends in party preference.
Finally, a and b, the parameters scaling our text-based ideology measures, are
sensitive to both the OLS regression coefficients on which channel is reported as most
watched as well as the coefficients on projected hours watched in the second stage
regressions. Separate identification of these parameters from ρ and η is possible because
there are three channels and thus six moments to work with. The asymmetries in the
channels’ estimated effects relative to their text-based ideological positioning provide
variation to distinguish the scaling parameters from ρ and η. To make this concrete,
consider the OLS estimates for Fox News and MSNBC. The Fox News coefficient is
more positive than the MSNBC coefficient is negative. Increasing η intensifies the
magnitude of both OLS coefficients generated from the model in similar proportions.
Increasing b at a fixed η increases the magnitude of the Fox News coefficient at a faster
rate than the MSNBC coefficient, because the text-based Fox News ideology is more
conservative than the text-based MSNBC ideology is liberal.
34
34
To test this intuition, we verified that the derivative of the model’s Fox News OLS coefficient with respect
to η is on the same order as the same derivative for the MSNBC OLS coefficient, while the derivative of the
model’s Fox News coefficient with respect to b is larger than that derivative for the MSNBC OLS coefficient.
38
6.2 Model Estimates
Table 11 shows the main parameter estimates from the model.
35
We estimate positive
values for both ρ, the influence parameter, and η, the taste for like-minded news,
implying a positive feedback process where voters watch slanted news, are influenced
to move closer to the news’ channel’s ideology, and subsequently have even stronger
preference for that channel, due to the decreased ideological distance.
Parameter Estimate Bootstrapped Standard Error
Slant Preference (η) 0.163 0.0109
Ideological Influence (ρ) 0.096 0.0080
Position Effect - Ratings -0.002 0.0002
Position Effect - Viewership -0.085 0.0030
2000 R/D Threshold -0.184 0.0130
2004 R/D Threshold 0.055 0.0127
2008 R/D Threshold 0.106 0.0167
Channel Ideology Intercept (a) -0.246 0.0179
Channel Ideology Slope (b) 5.378 0.2441
Table 11: Key parameter estimates.
The magnitude of the estimate of the taste for like minded news parameter η
implies that an ideological distance of one unit between viewer and channel reduces
that viewer’s probability of watching by about 16%. For reference, at our estimated
scaling parameters, the ideological distance between Fox News and MSNBC in 2008
is close to one unit. The magnitude of ρ implies that a voter watching an hour per
week of a news channel for a year would be influenced to a new ideological position
just under 10% of the distance to the channel’s ideology. Estimates of the channel
position parameters, consistent with the data, imply that increasing channel position
decreases both the probability of watching any of a channel, as well as the number of
hours watched conditional on watching any. The effect on the probability of watching
any - row 4 in the table - implies that doubling the channel position decreases the
probability of a typical voter watching a channel by about 8.5%.
35
The full set of parameters additionally contains channel-year fixed effects and demographic terms, sepa-
rately for the amount watched and the probability of watching any. These are omitted here for brevity. The
estimated model’s fit on regression coefficients is available in the Appendix.
39
The channel position effect on the number of hours watched is harder to interpret
directly, as the hours-watched model is nonlinear and hence effects of changing these
quantities depend on the values of all the other covariates. Tables 12 and 13 therefore
show some interpretable quantities generated by the model for viewers with various
demographic and ideological profiles.
Channel Position Elasticity
Age Income ($000s) Ethnicity College Gender Ideology CNN FOX MSNBC
65 25 White No Man Centrist 17.5 16.6 16.0
65 25 White No Man Median Republican 0.0 16.1 0.0
65 25 White No Man Median Democrat 16.4 13.4 15.9
30 85 Black Yes Man Centrist 15.8 11.7 13.6
30 85 Black Yes Man Median Republican 12.8 11.2 0.0
30 85 Black Yes Man Median Democrat 14.6 8.2 13.5
65 85 Hispanic No Man Centrist 20.8 16.8 16.3
65 85 Hispanic No Man Median Republican 18.0 16.3 0.0
65 85 Hispanic No Man Median Democrat 19.7 13.5 16.2
30 25 White Yes Woman Centrist 0.0 8.8 12.5
30 25 White Yes Woman Median Republican 0.0 7.4 0.0
30 25 White Yes Woman Median Democrat 0.0 0.0 12.4
65 25 Black No Woman Centrist 18.2 16.9 15.3
65 25 Black No Woman Median Republican 0.0 16.5 0.0
65 25 Black No Woman Median Democrat 17.1 13.7 15.3
30 85 Hispanic Yes Woman Centrist 14.6 9.0 12.8
30 85 Hispanic Yes Woman Median Republican 0.0 8.5 0.0
30 85 Hispanic Yes Woman Median Democrat 13.4 0.0 12.8
Table 12: Change in expected ratings (minutes watched per week) following a move from
channel position 50 to channel position 30, for selected demographic and ideological profiles.
Table 12 shows computed elasticities of viewers’ expected minutes watched with
respect to channel position. We compute the change in ratings (measured in minutes
per week) resulting from a channel’s moving from position 50 to position 30 in the
lineup.
36
All are weakly positive, as expected, although some are exactly zero because
the average viewer of the given demographic and ideological profile does not watch
any of the channel, regardless of position. Viewers’ demographics and initial ideologies
have an important influence on their sensitivity to channel position, with viewer-types
who initially watch more of a channel showing larger changes in minutes.
Table 13 shows a different look at the relationship of viewer preference for channels
to demographics and channel position. For the same ideological and demographic pro-
36
Positions 50 and 30 correspond approximately to the 75th and 25th percentile position, respectively, of
Fox News in 2008. We show the same channel position difference for all three channels to make the figures
comparable to each other.
40
Age Income ($000s) Ethnicity College Gender Ideology Channel Rank-Order FNC
MSNBC
65 25 White No Man Centrist FNC, CNN, MSNBC -2.25
65 25 White No Man Median Republican FNC, CNN, MSNBC -4.12
65 25 White No Man Median Democrat MSNBC, CNN, FNC 1.08
30 85 Black Yes Man Centrist CNN, MSNBC, FNC 0.47
30 85 Black Yes Man Median Republican FNC, CNN, MSNBC -2.98
30 85 Black Yes Man Median Democrat CNN, MSNBC, FNC 4.75
65 85 Hispanic No Man Centrist CNN, FNC, MSNBC -1.75
65 85 Hispanic No Man Median Republican FNC, CNN, MSNBC -4.71
65 85 Hispanic No Man Median Democrat CNN, MSNBC, FNC 1.44
30 25 White Yes Woman Centrist MSNBC, FNC, CNN 1.07
30 25 White Yes Woman Median Republican FNC, CNN, MSNBC -0.18
30 25 White Yes Woman Median Democrat MSNBC, CNN, FNC 1.83
65 25 Black No Woman Centrist FNC, CNN, MSNBC -2.59
65 25 Black No Woman Median Republican FNC, CNN, MSNBC -4.29
65 25 Black No Woman Median Democrat MSNBC, CNN, FNC 0.63
30 85 Hispanic Yes Woman Centrist CNN, MSNBC, FNC 1.63
30 85 Hispanic Yes Woman Median Republican FNC, CNN, MSNBC -1.22
30 85 Hispanic Yes Woman Median Democrat MSNBC, CNN, FNC 3.79
Table 13: Preference orderings of channels, and change in log channel position needed to flip
FNC / MSNBC preference order, for selected demographic profiles.
files as in the previous table, Table 13 lists that type of viewer’s preference ordering
over the three cable channels, on a hypothetical system where all three are available
and positioned at their median position in the data in 2008. The last column shows the
difference in log channel position that would be required to flip that type of viewer’s
preference between Fox and MSNBC. Demographic effects play a large role in deter-
mining the most preferred channel. Within demographic profiles, ideology can drive
differences in preferences: all Republican types prefer Fox News to MSNBC, and vice
versa for Democrats.
In both our raw data and in the simulations, slanted media are consumed by agents
who do not necessarily share the same ideology as the media outlet. This result is
consistent with the analysis in Gentzkow and Shapiro (2011) who find that much
of Fox News Channel’s audience is composed of people who do not self-identify as
conservative, and related, that self-identified conservatives watch other cable news
besides Fox News.
37
Our model estimates match these facts. Furthermore, such a
lack of ideological segregation is a necessary precursor in our model for cable news
consumption to change voter intentions.
37
Their results apply more broadly showing that individuals across the political spectrum tend to consume
media that is ideologically diverse.
41
Election Voter Ideology 1 Hour CNN 1 Hour FNC 1 Hour MSNBC
2000
Centrist -0.016 0.014 0.004
Median Republican -0.078 -0.054 -0.062
Median Democrat 0.048 0.073 0.065
2004
Centrist -0.003 0.022 0.005
Median Republican -0.069 -0.048 -0.062
Median Democrat 0.058 0.080 0.065
2008
Centrist -0.011 0.035 -0.036
Median Republican -0.076 -0.039 -0.097
Median Democrat 0.051 0.092 0.031
Table 14: Effects of watching an additional 1 hour per week on the probability of voting
Republican.
Election Voter Ideology CNN FNC MSNBC
2000
Median Republican 0.41 0.46 0.32
Median Democrat 0.62 0.35 0.32
2004
Median Republican 0.31 0.53 0.19
Median Democrat 0.41 0.36 0.20
2008
Median Republican 0.00 0.31 0.00
Median Democrat 0.12 0.00 0.20
Table 15: Probability of cable subscribers with access to the channel watching each channel
in each election year, for different ideological types.
We find that the perception of slant for the channels is a multiple of about five
times the text based slant measure. The text based slant measures place Fox News and
MSNBC in 2008 closer to the center than the median Republican or median Democratic
congressman, respectively. The scaled ideology estimates place Fox News close to the
median Republican voter.
Table 14 shows the change in the probability of voting Republican with respect
to watching one hour per week of each of the cable channels, again for viewers with
different initial ideological types. For initially centrist voters, watching additional CNN
has a small negative influence on the probability of voting Republican, by between 0
and 1.5 percentage points depending on the election. The effect of MSNBC is very
close to zero in 2000 and 2004, but becomes substantially negative (at 3.6 percentage
points) in 2008 after MSNBC’s format switch. The effect of Fox is positive, ranging
42
Election All voters Only attached voters
FNC (D to R) MSNBC (R to D) FNC (D to R) MSNBC (R to D)
2000 13% 12% 2% 3%
2004 34% 9% 17% 1%
2008 50% 30% 29% 23%
Table 16: Persuasion rates of Fox News and MSNBC. “All voters” counts as a Democrat
any voter initially to the left of the election cutoff, and counts as a Republican any voter
initially to the right. “Only attached voters” includes only voters in the leftmost 25% and
rightmost 25% of the voter ideology distribution. Percentages are conditional on watching
the channel.
from 1.4 point in 2000 to 3.5 points in 2008. The largest elasticity magnitudes are
on individuals from the opposite ideology of the channel, with Fox generally better at
influencing Democrats than MSNBC is at influencing Republicans. This last feature
is consistent with the regression result that the IV effect of Fox is greater than the
corresponding effect for MSNBC.
Table 15 shows the effects of viewers’ initial ideology on the probability that they
choose to watch each channel. The noteworthy pattern is that both Fox and MSNBC
appear to become more ideologically distinctive over time. In 2000, the difference be-
tween the probability of a typical Republican and that of a typical Democrat watching
Fox is about 11 percentage points; by 2008 that gap widens to over 30 points. For
MSNBC the difference is essentially zero in 2000 and 2004, but widens to 20 points by
2008.
Finally, Table 16 shows the estimated persuasion rates of the channels at converting
votes from one party to the other. The numerator here is the number of, for example,
Fox News viewers who are initially Democrats but by the end of an election cycle
change to supporting the Republican party. The denominator is the number of Fox
News viewers who are initially Democrats.
38
Again, Fox is more effective at converting
viewers than is MSNBC. The persuasion rates are high, and increasing over time as
the channels polarize. However, due to the taste for like-minded news, the effect on
the total number of votes converted is ambiguous; as shown in Table 15, there are far
fewer Democrats deciding to watch Fox News in 2008 than in 2000.
38
As our model has no inherent notion of partisanship, only an ideological cutpoint between the parties,
in Table 16 we consider two definitions of what constitutes a Democrat or Republican partisan.
43
7 Polarization Dynamics
In this section, we perform two exercises to quantify the effects of slanted cable news on
election outcomes. First, we simulate the evolution of ideology for groups of voters over
time to document the incidence of slanted cable news on these agents’ political ideolo-
gies. Second, we estimate the effect of the entry of Fox News on the 2000 presidential
election.
A positive ρ, implying that watching slanted news affects ideology, and a positive
η, implying a taste for like-minded news, together create the potential for a polarizing
feedback loop. Consider forcing a centrist voter to watch only the Fox News Channel.
The more that individual watches the Fox News Channel, the more they drift to the
right; the more they drift to the right, the more they are attracted to watching Fox
News, and so on. These two effects reinforce each other, in a positive feedback process
related to theoretical models from the literature on network formation (Holme and
Newman, 2006). In this section, we quantify the rate at which such polarization can
occur, given our model’s estimates. We employ the polarization index developed in
Esteban and Ray (1994) and Duclos et al. (2004).
Evolution of viewer ideology Figure 7 shows the results of a simulation of
viewing behavior given the model parameters estimated in the previous section. A
sample of 10,000 hypothetical viewers in an average cable system
39
in a county with
average demographic characteristics are initialized are assigned ideologies from the
initial ideology distribution for 2008, conditional on their simulated demographics.
In each year, they choose whether and how much to watch of each channel, given
individual-specific preferences. Their ideologies then adjust towards the ideology of
the channels they view in accordance with equation 6. This process repeats over the
next ten years.
The resulting distribution of ideologies changes according to two contrasting pat-
terns. Cable viewers who are initially centrist quickly polarize according to their chosen
channel, leading to the emergence of new poles at the ideologies of CNN, FNC, and
MSNBC respectively. The peaks of the distribution at those points become succes-
39
For purposes of this simulation, all viewers are given access to all three cable channels, at the channels’
mean positions in the data.
44
sively sharper in each year. However, for initially extreme cable viewers - those to the
right of FOX or to the left of MSNBC - watching cable news exerts a centralizing force.
Correspondingly, mass in the far tails of the ideology distribution declines.
Because of this combination of drawing in viewers from the extremes, and driving
apart those initially centrist, the aggregate effect of cable news on ideological polar-
ization is ambiguous and not easily discerned from plots like that in Figure 7. We
therefore turn to the work of Esteban and Ray (1994); Duclos et al. (2004), who pro-
vide a measure of polarization derived from axioms. Employing their measure on
simulated individuals, we find that the existence of cable news increases polarization.
Interestingly, this increase in polarization is dependent on the existence of a taste for
like-minded news; without such a taste, cable news actually reduces polarization. The
first row in Table 17 presents this polarization measure at the initial ideology distri-
bution for the presidential election cycle in question. The second row presents the
polarization measure after four years of watching cable news. The third row presents
the same measure, but shutting down the taste for like-minded news.
40
Without a
taste for congruent news, viewers from across the political spectrum would be exposed
to and persuaded by news from the other side.
2000 2004 2008
Initial 0.439 0.439 0.440
Post-Exposure 0.455 0.503 0.470
Post-Exposure (no slant preference) 0.412 0.420 0.396
Table 17: Esteban and Ray polarization measure, before and after exposure to cable news.
Fox Entry in 2000 Next, we estimated the effect of the entry of Fox News into the
cable news market beginning in late 1996 on the 2000 presidential election. Using our
estimated model parameters, we simulated two conditions. First, a base case where Fox
was available to cable subscribers in the 1997-2000 period according to the observed
rollout pattern. Second, a scenario where Fox was available exclusively to satellite
subscribers and not on any local cable system. We computed aggregate viewer welfare
and aggregate vote outcomes under each scenario.
40
I.e., we set the parameter η equal to zero, rather than the estimated value.
45
Year 1 Year 2 Year 3
Year 4 Year 5 Year 6
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
−2 0 2 −2 0 2 −2 0 2
Ideology
density
Figure 7: Density plots of viewers’ ideology over time. Voters are initially drawn from the
unconditional ideology distribution in 2008. The remaining 5 plots show the change in the
ideology distribution over time, in years 2 through 6.
46
Cycle Intention Intention (voters) Welfare Substitution
2000 -0.013 -0.009 -0.38 0.87
2004 -0.057 -0.040 -0.34 0.84
2008 -0.059 -0.042 -0.40 0.80
Table 18: Effects of elimination of the Fox News Channel from cable lineups. Column 2 is the
change in the Republican share of the presidential vote intention; column 3 rescales these to
approximate the effects on registered voters only; column 4 is the average fractional change
in welfare from cable TV of Fox viewers; column 5 is the fraction of initial Fox viewers who
switch to CNN or MSNBC after Fox is eliminated.
Table 18 shows the effects of eliminating Fox from cable lineups in the 1997-2000
period and subsequent election cycles. County-level Republican vote shares on aver-
age fall by 1.3 percentage points under the no-Fox scenario relative to the baseline.
This prediction is roughly an order of magnitude higher than the previous estimate
of DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007).
41
We note that because our simulation model pre-
dicts vote intention, and not actual votes,
42
these estimates overstate the effect on
actual election outcomes. As a rough estimate of the importance of this compositional
difference between the NAES sample and the population of voters, we scale our coun-
terfactual vote changes down in proportion to the reduction in the 2SLS effect seen
when we restrict our regression sample to registered voters (discussed in section 4.2).
Welfare from cable news of those cable subscribers who watched some Fox under the
baseline scenario but could not in the no-Fox case falls as well, by about 40% overall.
The welfare loss is mitigated to some degree by the availability of substitutes in CNN
and MSNBC; large majorities of former Fox viewers switch to watching one of the other
two channels when Fox availablility is eliminated.
We also repeat this no-Fox counterfactual exercise in the two subsequent election
cycles. In subsequent cycles, the implied Fox News effect increases due to two forces.
First and most importantly, overall Fox News viewership approximately doubles during
the period 2000 to 2008, meaning nearly twice as many viewers are exposed to Fox News
41
One can attribute the differences to measurement error in the DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) study
detailed in Appendix A of this paper. Furthermore, their study considers only a subset of geographies for
which they could obtain voting data whereas our estimates cover the universe of US cable systems.
42
The underlying data come from the NAES, which surveyed a random sample of American adults, not
all of whom are likely voters or even registered to vote.
47
in later cycles. Second, Fox News moves to the right, increasing its persuasive effect
enough to outweigh any loss in viewership due to the ideological drift. Finally, as Fox
becomes more ideologically distinctive over time, the proportion of its viewers who find
MSNBC or CNN to be acceptable substitutes falls as well.
MSNBC Format Switch Finally, we estimated the effects of MSNBC’s format
switch to providing more explicitly liberal coverage in 2005. We simulated a condition
where MSNBC’s ideology matched that of CNN, and compared to our base case. Table
19 shows that the estimated effect in the 2008 election cycle of this switch is to increase
the Republican share of presidential vote intention by over 4 percentage points, an effect
somewhat smaller but comparable in magnitude to the estimated effect of eliminating
Fox News. This change induces welfare losses of MSNBC subscribers, who prefer the
base case ideology; however, preferences are not as strong as those of Fox viewers.
For comparison purposes, we also run this scenario for the earlier two election cycles,
showing that prior to 2005, MSNBC was a net conservative force.
Cycle Intention Intention (voters) Welfare
2000 -0.016 -0.011 -0.25
2004 -0.019 -0.013 -0.16
2008 0.043 0.030 -0.20
Table 19: Effects of setting MSNBC’s ideology to match that of CNN. Column 2 is the
change in the Republican share of the presidential vote intention; column 3 rescales these to
approximate the effects on registered voters only; column 4 is the average percentage change
in welfare from cable TV of MSNBC viewers.
8 Conclusion
This paper provides estimates of both the influence of slanted news on political views
and the taste for like-minded news in the context of cable television news in the U.S. The
key ingredient in the analysis is the use of channel positions as instrumental variables to
estimate a model of viewership, voting, and ideology evolution. We show instrumental
variables estimates that watching the Fox News Channel increases the probability of
48
voting Republican, and watching MSNBC after 2004 decreases the probability of voting
Republican in presidential elections.
We estimate a model of consumer-viewer-voters who choose cable subscriptions, al-
locate time to watching news channels, and vote in elections. The tastes for news chan-
nels are partly determined by the closeness of the news channels’ estimated ideology
to the individuals. Individual ideology evolves towards the estimated ideologies of the
news channels that a consumer watches. We use the estimated model to characterize
the degree of polarization that one can attribute to slanted cable news consumption,
and measure effects on elections. Our estimates imply large effects of Fox News on
presidential elections. Furthermore, we estimate that cable news does increase polar-
ization, and that this increase depends on both a persuasive effect of cable news and
the existence of tastes for like-minded news.
Future research could go in a number of directions. The use of channel positions
as instrumental variable could be useful in other studies of how media consumption
affects behavior. One could also use channel position variation to study the cable
news channels in more detail by examining specific programs, e.g. “The O’Reilly
Factor,” and specific issues like abortion, gay marriage, or government spending. In a
different direction, studying the causes and consequences of the divergence in estimated
ideologies seems fruitful.
43
It would also be useful to test, refine, or expand the specific
model we employ for belief updating after media consumption. For example, one could
allow for a joint distribution of influence parameters and tastes for like-minded news
in the population.
43
This includes improving these text based procedures to allow for sentiment analysis or other partisan
indicators.
49
References
Ansolabehere, Stephen, “CCES, Common Content, 2008,” 2011.
, Maxwell Palmer, and Amanda Lee, “Precinct-Level Election Data,” 2014.
Arceneaux, Kevin, Martin Johnson, and Chad Murphy, “Polarized political
communication, oppositional media hostility, and selective exposure,” The Journal
of Politics, 2012, 74 (01), 174–186.
Black, Eric and Tom Hamburger, “Major event, minor coverage: GOP debate
won’t make networks,” Star Tribune: Newspaper of the Twin Cities, December 1999.
Chiang, Chun-Fang and Brian Knight, “Media bias and influence: Evidence from
newspaper endorsements,” The Review of Economic Studies, 2011, 78 (3), 795.
Colman, Price, “TCI will carry Fox news channel,” Broadcasting & Cable, July 1996.
Crawford, Gregory S and Ali Yurukoglu, “The welfare effects of bundling in
multichannel television markets,” The American Economic Review, 2012, 102 (2),
643–685.
DellaVigna, Stefano and Ethan Kaplan, “The Fox News effect: Media bias and
voting,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2007, 122 (3), 1187–1234.
DeMarzo, Peter M, Dimitri Vayanos, and Jeffrey Zwiebel, “Persuasion bias,
social influence, and unidimensional opinions,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
2003, 118 (3), 909–968.
Dempsey, John, “Spurned cable webs revile TCI,” Variety, August 1996.
Duclos, Jean-Yves, Joan Esteban, and Debraj Ray, “Polarization: concepts,
measurement, estimation,” Econometrica, 2004, 72 (6), 1737–1772.
Enikolopov, Ruben, Maria Petrova, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya, “Media and
political persuasion: Evidence from Russia,” The American Economic Review, 2011,
101 (7), 3253–3285.
50
Esteban, Joan-Maria and Debraj Ray, “On the measurement of polarization,”
Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 1994, pp. 819–851.
Galesic, Mirta, Roger Tourangeau, Mick P Couper, and Frederick G Con-
rad, “Eye-Tracking data new insights on response order effects and other cognitive
shortcuts in survey responding,” Public Opinion Quarterly, 2008, 72 (5), 892–913.
Gentzkow, Matthew, “Television and voter turnout,” The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 2006, 121 (3), 931–972.
and Jesse M. Shapiro, “Media Bias and Reputation,” Journal of Political Econ-
omy, 2006, 114 (2), 280–316.
and , “Competition and Truth in the Market for News,” The Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 2008, pp. 133–154.
and , “What drives media slant? Evidence from US daily newspapers,” Econo-
metrica, 2010, 78 (1), 35–71.
and , “Ideological segregation online and offline,” The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 2011, 126 (4), 1799–1839.
and , “Measuring the Sensitivity of Parameter Estimates to Sample Statistics,”
2013. Working Paper.
Gerber, Alan S., Dean Karlan, and Daniel Bergan, “Does the Media Matter?
A Field Experiment Measuring the Effect of Newspapers on Voting Behavior and
Political Opinions,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2009, 1 (2),
35–52.
Gourieroux, Christian, Alain Monfort, and Eric Renault, “Indirect inference,”
Journal of Applied Econometrics, 1993, 8 (S1), S85–S118.
Groseclose, Tim and Jeffrey Milyo, “A measure of media bias,” The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 2005, pp. 1191–1237.
Holme, Petter and Mark E.J. Newman, “Nonequilibrium phase transition in the
coevolution of networks and opinions,” Physical Review E, 2006, 74 (5), 056108.
51
Horan, Sean, “Sequential search and choice from lists,” Unpublished paper., 2010.
Inoue, Atsushi and Gary Solon, “Two-sample instrumental variables estimators,”
The Review of Economics and Statistics, 2010, 92 (3), 557–561.
Leighley, Jan E. and Jonathan Nagler, Who Votes Now?: Demographics, Issues,
Inequality, and Turnout in the United States, Princeton University Press, 2013.
Lim, Claire S.H., James M. Snyder Jr., and David Stromberg, “The Judge,
the Politician, and the Press: Newspaper Coverage and Criminal Sentencing Across
Electoral Systems,” Working paper., 2014.
Lohse, Gerald L, “Consumer eye movement patterns on yellow pages advertising,”
Journal of Advertising, 1997, 26 (1), 61–73.
Masatlioglu, Yusufcan and Daisuke Nakajima, “Choice by iterative search,”
Theoretical Economics, 2013, 8 (3), 701–728.
McCarty, Nolan M, Keith T Poole, and Howard Rosenthal, “Income redistri-
bution and the realignment of American politics,” 1997.
Mullainathan, Sendhil and Andrei Shleifer, “The market for news,” American
Economic Review, 2005, pp. 1031–1053.
Rubinstein, Ariel and Yuval Salant, “A model of choice from lists,” Theoretical
Economics, 2006, 1 (1), 3–17.
Sanneh, Kelefa, “Twenty-Four Hour Party People: MSNBC tries to figure out what
liberals really want.,” The New Yorker, September 2013.
Smith, Anthony Alan, “Three essays on the solution and estimation of dynamic
macroeconomic models.” PhD dissertation, Duke University 1990.
Zou, Hui and Trevor Hastie, “Regularization and variable selection via the elastic
net,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B (Statistical Methodology),
2005, 67 (2), 301–320.
52
A DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007)
DellaVigna and Kaplan (2007) (henceforth DVK) compare changes in presidential vote
shares in towns which had access to the Fox News Channel by the year 2000 compared
to towns that did not conditional on a rich set of co-variates. The first-order problem
in DVK’s data is severe mis-measurement due to non-updated entries. Specifically,
37% of control group observations, the towns which the DVK data indicate did not
have cable access to the Fox News Channel in the year 2000, actually did have access
to Fox News, but were not properly updated in that data source. In fact, about 25%
of these towns already had cable access to the Fox News Channel in 1998. When one
re-runs their specifications with the Nielsen FOCUS data,
44
one draws new inferences
from the estimated coefficients in DVK’s two preferred specifications.
In the specification with county-level fixed effects, the coefficient on having access
to Fox News drops from 0.00694 to 0.00215, and is no longer statistically significant. In
the specification with district-level fixed effects, the coefficient on having access to Fox
News remains roughly the same. However, this specification now performs poorly on
the placebo test that DVK used to argue that the estimate is not driven by selection of
towns into having access to the Fox News Channel. The estimated coefficient of cable
availability of Fox News in 2000 on the change in Republican vote share from 1992 to
1996 is nearly the same as the estimated coefficient for the change between 1996 and
2000.
45
A.1 The Data Problem
The data source in DVK is the Warren’s Cable and Television Factbook (henceforth
Factbook). The Factbook updates only a minority of cable systems every year. The
extent of non-updating has been documented by Crawford and Yurukoglu (2012). We
reproduce the relevant years from their Appendix table below in Table 20. Updating
is especially poor around DVK sample year. Between 1999 and 2000, only 22% of
observations were updated. Between 1998 and 1999, only 37% of observations were
44
These data are discussed in Section 3. We detail in the next subsection why the Factbook data are not
suitable for evaluating the effects of Fox News in 2000 while the Nielsen FOCUS data are.
45
The former is not statistically distinguishable from the latter nor from zero. The placebo estimate
(0.00296) is closer to the actual estimate (0.0037) than it is to zero.
53
updated. Since Fox News was expanding across the country rapidly during these years,
this infrequent updating is consequential: many towns in the Factbook were listed as
not having cable access to Fox News, when in fact they did but the Factbook simply
wasn’t updated yet. Nearly all systems in the Nielsen FOCUS data are updated every
year.
Table 20: Data Quality of Factbook
Year Variable Number of Bundles Fraction of Bundles
1998 Total bundles 15,743 100.0%
Full information 10,872 69.0%
Updated 4,714 30.0%
Full information and updated 3,461 22.0%
1999 Total bundles 15,497 100.0%
Full information 10,444 67.0%
Updated 5,663 37.0%
Full information and updated 3,595 23.0%
2000 Total bundles 15,453 100.0%
Full information 10,312 67.0%
Updated 3,358 22.0%
Full information and updated 2,478 16.0%
2001 Total bundles 15,391 100.0%
Full information 9,793 64.0%
Updated 4,173 27.0%
Full information and updated 2,663 17.0%
2002 Total bundles 15,287 100.0%
Full information 7,776 51.0%
Updated 5,086 33.0%
Full information and updated 1,484 10.0%
1997-2007 Total bundles 166,619 100.0%
Full information 91,100 55.0%
Updated 62,299 37.0%
Full information and updated 31,493 19.0%
Notes: This table is a reproduction from Crawford and Yurukoglu (2012) indicating the degree of non-updating
in Factbook data.
One can verify that the Nielsen FOCUS data are accurate, while the non-updated
Factbook data are not. First, one can cross check the data sources against newspa-
pers from the time period. Black and Hamburger (1999) is a newspaper article from
December 2, 1999 stating that “Fox News Channel is channel 21B to subscribers in
Minneapolis.” According to the Factbook data used in DVK, Minneapolis did not have
54
access to the Fox News Channel by November 2000. The Nielsen FOCUS data indi-
cate that Minneapolis did have access to Fox News Channel in 1999, and also correctly
indicates the channel number of 21B. Second, we investigated the systems with the
largest discrepancy: those where Nielsen FOCUS indicated had Fox News availability
in 1998 while the Factbook indicated no availability by 2000. 353 of these systems
were operated by Tele-Communcations Inc. (TCI) in 1998. Press reports from the
time period indicate that Fox News would be available to over 90% of TCI customers
by 1998 (Colman (1996)).
Finally, the number of subscribers for Fox News implied by the Factbook data
conflict with the amount of viewership Fox News had in 2000, including the viewership
data used in DVK. According to DVK, “About half of the Fox News audience, therefore,
watches Fox News in ways other than via cable, possibly via satellite. This finding could
also be due to measurement error in our measure of availability via cable.” According
to their data, 17% of households were watching Fox News in 2000. Therefore, 8.5% of
all households must have been simultaneously satellite subscribers and watching Fox
News. However, the market share of satellite in the year 2000 was 11.4%
46
Therefore,
a vast majority of satellite subscribers must have been watching Fox News in 2000 to
be consistent with the Factbook availability measures. Our Mediamark data indicate
that the fraction of satellite subscribers watching Fox News in 2000 is only 19%.
47
To correct this issue, we matched the voting and demographic data in DVK to
Nielsen FOCUS. The identification numbers in the Factbook and Nielsen FOCUS do
not match. We employed a matching procedure based on community names and firm
names, using manual inspection when matches weren’t obvious. We were able to re-
liably match 8,286 observations out of 9,256 to Nielsen FOCUS. Tables 21 and 22
compare the availability of Fox News according to the two data sources.
About 40 percent of the control group in DVK is mis-classified as not having cable
access to Fox News. About 25 percent already had access in 1998 and hadn’t been
updated for at least two years in the Factbook.
46
The cable market share was 70.2% implying a 81.6% total market share. Thus, about 14% of cable or
satellite subscribers were satellite subscribers.
47
Their viewership data and our Mediamark data agree on the aggregate 17% number. Our Mediamark
data indicate the conditional probability of watching Fox News conditional on satellite is only marginally
higher at 19%.
55
Factbook Fox News
(Year 2000)
0 1 Total
Nielsen Fox News
(Year 2000)
0 3,632 58 3,690
1 3,076 1,520 4,596
Total 6,708 1,578 8,286
Table 21: Year 2000: Nielsen Fox News Availability and Factbook non-updated Fox News
Availability.
Factbook Fox News
(Year 2000)
0 1 Total
Nielsen Fox News
(Year 1998)
0 4,837 358 5,195
1 1,871 1,220 3,091
Total 6,708 1,578 8,286
Table 22: Nielsen Fox News Availability in 1998 and Factbook non-updated Fox News Avail-
ability in 2000.
A.2 Estimates with Nielsen Data
We now re-run the two “benchmark” specifications from DVK: the county level fixed
effects regression and the US House district level fixed effects regression. These corre-
spond to equation (2) in DVK. Table 23 compares the resulting estimates.
The estimate in the county level fixed effects regression drops from a statistically
significant 0.00694 (Column 7) to 0.00215 (Column 9), and becomes statistically in-
distinguishable from no effect of Fox News on change in Republican vote share. The
difference cannot be attributed to not matching all of DVK’s observations. Their es-
timated effect is stronger when using their Fox variable, but only on the subset of
matching observations (Column 8).
The estimate in the Congressional district fixed effects regression remains stable
with the Nielsen data. However, this specification delivers new results in the placebo
test DVK use to argue that their specifications are estimating the causal effects of Fox
News rather than selection of towns trending Republican into carrying Fox News. Table
24 compares the placebo regression estimates using the original data and the corrected
data. Using the correct data, the placebo regression indicates that availability of Fox
56
Republican two-party vote share change between 2000 and 1996 pres. elections
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Factbook Fox 0.00798*** 0.00869*** 0.00421*** 0.00473*** 0.00694*** 0.00741***
(0.00257) (0.00270) (0.00154) (0.00163) (0.00150) (0.00158)
Nielsen Fox 0.00786*** 0.00377*** 0.00215
(0.00171) (0.00117) (0.00131)
Observations 9,256 8,286 8,286 9,256 8,286 8,286 9,256 8,286 8,286
R-squared 0.557 0.559 0.561 0.753 0.755 0.755 0.812 0.815 0.814
Data Set Factbook Factbook Nielsen Factbook Factbook Nielsen Factbook Factbook Nielsen
Sample Full Matched Matched Full Matched Matched Full Matched Matched
FE OLS OLS OLS District District District County County County
Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by cable firm
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 23: OLS, District FE, and County FE specifications from DVK and with corrected Fox News availability
data.
57
News might very well be positively correlated with the change in Republican vote
share between 1992 and 1996 in the district fixed effect specification. The coefficient’s
precision can not rule out a zero effect, but the district fixed effects regression should
be interpreted in light of the placebo results.
B Comparison of Regression Coefficients in Real
and Simulated Data
This section reports the fit of the indirect inference estimation routine. Tables 25, 26,
and 27 report the fit for the first and second stages, respectively.
C More on Channel Positions
The combination of the placebo test of whether cable channel positions predict view-
ership of news channels on satellite together with the institutional narrative of the
period 1992-2000 is the most convincing argument for the validity of channel positions
as instrumental variables for the effect of watching cable news on voting Republican.
In this section, we provide additional evidence in support of the validity for the in-
strumental variables assumption. First, we show that cable channels whose viewership
is composed of similar demographics have uncorrelated channel positions. Second, we
show that Fox News and MSNBC channel positions are highly correlated with the best
available position on the system at the time they were added. Third, we carry out
the formal test for whether local cable position effects are equal for cable and satellite
subscribers.
C.1 Channel Positions for Channels with Similar Demo-
graphics
If channel positions are tailored to local tastes, one would expect channels whose view-
ership is composed of similar demographics would have correlated channel positions.
We examine this possibility in the data. The results are in Table 28. First, the Fox
News Channel position is positively correlated with the MSNBC position despite their
58
Republican two-party vote share change between 1996 and 1992 pres. elections
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Factbook Fox 0.00539 0.00459 -0.00237 -0.00271
(0.00503) (0.00507) (0.00313) (0.00325)
Nielsen Fox 0.00702** 0.00296
(0.00337) (0.00205)
Observations 4,006 3,637 3,637 4,006 3,637 3,637
R-squared 0.327 0.337 0.341 0.620 0.625 0.626
Data Set Factbook Factbook Nielsen Factbook Factbook Nielsen
Sample Full Matched Matched Full Matched Matched
Specification OLS OLS OLS District FE District FE District FE
Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by cable firm
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 24: OLS and District FE Placebo specifications from DVK and with corrected Fox News availability
data.
59
differences in slant. This is perhaps because they are both news channels, and some
system managers prefer to group same genre channels together even if they cater to
different segments of the population. Compare Columns (2) and (3) to see which other
channel positions correlate with Fox News and MSNBC positions. There is one chan-
nel, Bravo, which suggests endogenous positioning. During the sample period, Bravo
reformatted as a channel catering to younger and more urban viewers, including some
of the first programming to include gay characters in lead roles. Indeed, the Bravo
position is negatively correlated with the Fox Position, and positively correlated with
the MSNBC position. On the other hand, most of the other coefficients tell a different
story. Comedy Central, which airs the liberal slanted Daily Show and Colbert Report,
is negatively correlated with MSNBC. Country Music Television (CMT) is positively
correlated with MSNBC. The Trinity Broadcasting Network (TBN) which is explicitly
religious is negatively correlated with Fox News. Column (4) shows that Speed Chan-
nel, which airs coverage of NASCAR and other motorsports, is positively correlated
with Bravo.
C.2 Best Available Channel Position
We demonstrate one example of this historical influence in Table 29. We regress the
ordinal positions of Fox News and MSNBC on the system’s best available ordinal
position in 1997, along with a control for the overall size of the system - its total
number of channels.
48
The best available position in 1998 is a strong predictor of
the current position, even though the positioning data here extends through 2008. A
system’s channel configuration prior to the addition of Fox or MSNBC exerts a lasting
influence on the positioning of Fox and MSNBC today.
48
Our lineup data begins in 1998, and hence we restrict the sample for this regression to cable systems
that did not have Fox/MSNBC in 1998. “Best available” is defined as the lowest open slot (unoccupied by
an existing channel) in the region of the lineup dedicated to cable (i.e. non-network and non-local-access)
channels. We define the cable region by locating the positions of CNN, ESPN, TNT, and The Discovery
Channel, and consider any open slot above at least one of those channels to be available.
60
C.3 Chow Test for Positions
This subsection formally carries out the Chow tests for whether the local cable position
affects satellite subscribers in the same manner it affects cable subscribers. This differ-
ence between this regression and Tables 5 and 6 is that here we restrict the demographic
coefficients to be equal for both sets of subscribers.
D Other Outcome Variables
In this section, we explore the effect of cable news on other measures of political par-
tisanship aside from the surveyed Presidential vote variable. We look at self-reported
ideology on a 1 to 5 scale (Very conservative, Conservative, Moderate, Liberal, and
Very liberal) as well as precinct level actual vote tallies from the 2008 election.
D.1 Self-reported Ideology
Table 31 presents the results for self reported ideology. The Fox News effect corresponds
to one-quarter of a standard deviation of self-reported ideology for an extra hour per
week. The MSNBC effect is statistically imprecise. Interestingly, there is a liberal
CNN effect of about one-sixth of a standard deviation for an extra hour of CNN per
week.
D.2 2008 Precinct Level Vote Shares
We regress two party vote share at the precinct level on cable news channel positions
using the data set compiled by Ansolabehere et al. (2014). The advantage of these
data is that they capture actual realized vote totals. However, because we do not have
precinct level viewership, we can not directly estimate the viewership effect. Across a
variety of specifications, higher positions for Fox News predict a lower Republican vote
share, and higher positions of MSNBC predict a higher Republican vote share.
61
CNN-Positive FNC-Positive MSNBC-Positive
Regressor Real Simulated Real Simulated Real Simulated
CNN Position -0.087 -0.172 -0.005 0.032 -0.046 -0.013
FOX Position -0.012 0.004 -0.043 -0.261 0.041 0.030
MSN Position 0.034 -0.052 0.038 0.015 -0.001 -0.175
2000 3.837 3.520 2.791 2.281 2.844 3.210
2001 4.515 4.970 3.163 2.918 3.095 3.367
2002 4.492 4.404 3.470 3.092 2.989 3.305
2003 4.179 4.157 3.417 3.054 2.916 3.399
2004 4.333 4.098 3.699 3.178 2.960 3.724
2005 4.301 4.175 3.612 3.942 2.927 3.433
2006 4.113 3.966 3.437 3.205 2.908 3.128
2007 4.167 4.039 3.478 3.334 2.843 3.073
2008 6.446 7.141 6.897 3.864 5.878 6.033
FOX Only 0.125 -0.056 0.490 1.087 -0.450 -0.122
MSN Only -0.101 0.115 -0.548 0.088 0.096 0.774
Both Available -0.022 0.061 -0.004 1.023 -0.224 0.681
Income -0.899 -0.693 -0.244 -0.300 -0.746 -0.454
Income
2
0.348 0.256 -0.076 0.015 0.299 0.096
Income
3
-0.019 -0.014 0.048 0.016 -0.018 0.024
Age -0.020 -0.027 -0.016 -0.022 -0.011 -0.044
Age
2
0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.000 0.001
White -0.323 -0.256 0.391 0.081 -0.139 0.059
Black 0.151 0.206 0.191 0.078 0.232 -0.227
Hispanic -0.025 0.099 -0.152 0.018 0.084 -0.082
College Graduate 0.021 -0.024 -0.179 -0.106 -0.140 -0.066
Man 0.010 0.090 0.042 0.047 -0.049 -0.075
Log Number of Channels -0.135 -0.084 -0.163 -0.089 -0.015 -0.082
Table 25: Comparison of regression coefficients in real data and simulations. Dependent
variable is hours watched of each channel, conditional on watching any.
62
CNN-Zero FNC-Zero MSNBC-Zero
Regressor Real Simulated Real Simulated Real Simulated
CNN Position -0.013 -0.030 -0.001 -0.002 -0.001 0.001
FOX Position 0.000 -0.005 -0.018 -0.037 0.009 0.001
MSN Position -0.005 -0.005 0.011 -0.004 -0.033 -0.042
2000 -0.004 0.013 -0.235 -0.245 -0.131 -0.089
2001 0.041 0.010 -0.179 -0.246 -0.103 -0.082
2002 0.042 0.049 -0.138 -0.215 -0.123 -0.109
2003 0.016 0.027 -0.121 -0.202 -0.094 -0.084
2004 0.005 0.027 -0.091 -0.164 -0.096 -0.082
2005 0.013 0.023 -0.081 -0.214 -0.076 -0.070
2006 -0.004 0.010 -0.095 -0.194 -0.099 -0.081
2007 -0.016 0.007 -0.096 -0.181 -0.095 -0.072
2008 -0.157 -0.137 -0.225 -0.302 -0.198 -0.191
FOX Only 0.045 0.030 0.124 0.373 -0.022 0.003
MSN Only 0.083 0.027 -0.018 0.009 0.205 0.340
Both Available 0.068 0.051 0.077 0.390 0.160 0.333
Income 0.348 0.358 0.262 0.180 0.209 0.179
Income
2
-0.129 -0.082 -0.107 -0.034 -0.077 -0.054
Income
3
0.013 0.005 0.011 0.000 0.008 0.002
Age 0.003 0.005 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.002
Age
2
0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
White -0.025 -0.019 0.030 0.007 -0.001 -0.023
Black 0.020 0.017 0.057 0.061 0.007 0.013
Hispanic -0.041 -0.035 -0.042 -0.033 -0.030 -0.031
College Graduate 0.063 0.064 -0.019 -0.012 0.040 0.043
Man 0.043 0.047 0.048 0.047 0.038 0.036
Log Number of Channels -0.001 -0.003 0.008 -0.012 0.004 -0.008
Table 26: Comparison of regression coefficients in real data and simulations. Dependent
variable is an indicator for watching any of the channel.
63
Vote Intention - IV Vote Intention - OLS
Regressor Real Simulated Real Simulated
CNN Time 0.009 -0.011
FOX Time 0.138 0.125
MSN Time -0.103 -0.076
CNN Most-Watched -0.087 -0.087
FOX Most-Watched 0.329 0.331
MSN Most-Watched -0.095 -0.099
2000 0.741 0.699
2004 0.693 0.722 0.648 0.823
2008 0.682 0.772 0.649 0.854
FOX Only 0.009 -0.007 0.060 0.065
MSN Only 0.066 0.069 0.085 0.033
Both Available 0.037 0.018 0.060 0.060
Income 0.382 0.018 0.430 0.023
Income
2
-0.341 -0.014 -0.314 -0.006
Income
3
0.091 0.002 0.073 0.000
Age 0.003 0.002 0.003 0.000
Age
2
0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000
White 0.074 0.028 0.103 0.038
Black -0.354 -0.031 -0.286 -0.012
Hispanic -0.060 -0.018 -0.092 -0.020
College Graduate -0.060 0.004 -0.056 -0.011
Man 0.053 -0.006 0.044 0.004
Log Number of Channels -0.095 -0.064 -0.102 -0.087
Table 27: Comparison of regression coefficients in real data and simulations. Dependent
variable is Republican vote intention.
64
(1) (2) (3) (4)
VARIABLES Fox News Position Fox News Position MSNBC Position SPEED Position
ESPN Position 0.0377* 0.0761***
(0.0210) (0.0217)
TNT Position -0.0281 0.0391
(0.0228) (0.0279)
USA Position 9.66e-06 -0.141***
(0.0216) (0.0255)
Bravo Position -0.0449*** 0.0823*** 0.311***
(0.0112) (0.0153) (0.0271)
Comedy Central Position 0.00983 -0.0483**
(0.0194) (0.0206)
Trinity Broadcasting Network Position -0.0142** -0.00180
(0.00579) (0.00627)
CMT Position 0.00308 0.0528*** 0.0120
(0.00928) (0.0107) (0.0184)
SPEED Position -0.00318 0.00922
(0.00593) (0.00662)
N Channels 0.0184*** 0.0267*** -0.00975** 0.244***
(0.00221) (0.00434) (0.00480) (0.00835)
MSNBC Position 0.324***
(0.0161)
Observations 47,524 26,173 24,591 40,464
R-squared 0.154 0.022 0.031 0.186
Year Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes
Robust standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 28: Channel positions regressed on other channel positions.
65
Coefficient MSNBC Fox
(Intercept) 33.8 30.7
(0.573) (0.432)
Number of Channels 0.032 0.032
(0.003) (0.002)
Best Available 0.181 0.148
(0.014) (0.012)
R
2
0.066 0.077
N 29,337 38,328
Table 29: Ordinal channel position vs. best available ordinal channel position, among sys-
tems where the channel (MSNBC or Fox News) was added in 1998 or later. Standard errors
clustered by cable system.
(1) (2) (3)
VARIABLES Fox News Hours CNN Hours MSNBC Hours
FNC Cable Position x Cable -0.122*** -0.0316 0.0500***
(0.0214) (0.0210) (0.0132)
FNC Cable Position x Satellite -0.00617 0.0328 0.00273
(0.0457) (0.0449) (0.0282)
CNN Cable Position x Cable -0.0126 -0.112*** -0.0139
(0.0137) (0.0135) (0.00849)
CNN Cable Position x Satellite 0.00759 0.0137 -0.00864
(0.0311) (0.0306) (0.0192)
MSNBC Cable Position x Cable 0.129*** 0.0718*** -0.0973***
(0.0232) (0.0228) (0.0143)
MSNBC Cable Position x Satellite 0.0511 0.0135 0.0111
(0.0500) (0.0491) (0.0309)
Observations 168,862 168,862 168,862
R-squared 0.038 0.041 0.013
F Stat for Own Position x Cable = Own Position x Satellite 5.320 14.14 10.18
P Value for Own Position x Cable = Own Position x Satellite 0.0211 0.000170 0.00142
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 30: Chow Tests for whether cable position affects cable subscribers and satellite sub-
scribers equally.
66
(1)
VARIABLES Intent to Vote R
Fox News Channel Hours 0.233***
(0.0234)
CNN Hours -0.174***
(0.0428)
MSNBC Hours -0.0300
(0.0480)
HH Income 0.00369***
(0.000622)
HH Income
2
-2.65e-05***
(6.59e-06)
HH Income
3
6.21e-08***
(1.96e-08)
Age 0.0157***
(0.00135)
Age
2
-0.000104***
(2.01e-05)
White 0.0236
(0.0161)
Black -0.127***
(0.0164)
Hispanic -0.00404
(0.0131)
College -0.142***
(0.0120)
Male 0.147***
(0.00734)
log(N Channels) -0.208***
(0.0101)
Observations 119,524
R-squared 0.038
Year Effects Yes
Channel Availability Yes
Standard errors in parentheses
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 31: Second Stage regressions of NAES and CCES self-reported ideology on predicted
hours watched from the first stage.
67
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES R Vote Share R Vote Share R Vote Share R Vote Share R Vote Share R Vote Share
log(Fox News Position) -0.0100 -0.0135 -0.0106* -0.0115* -0.00650* -0.00756**
(0.00841) (0.00831) (0.00613) (0.00613) (0.00348) (0.00347)
log(MSNBC Position) 0.0229** 0.0202** 0.00653 0.00388 -0.000393 0.000428
(0.00986) (0.00968) (0.00775) (0.00750) (0.00427) (0.00440)
log(CNN Position) 0.00578 0.00352 -0.00279 -0.00268 0.00178 0.00202
(0.00643) (0.00635) (0.00466) (0.00451) (0.00265) (0.00270)
Observations 23,107 23,107 21,874 21,874 21,874 21,874
R-squared 0.129 0.154 0.478 0.493 0.710 0.717
Channel Availability Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Demographics No No Yes Yes Yes Yes
Number of Channels Log Log Log Log Log Log
Number of OTA Broadcast Log Full Set Log Full Set Log Full Set
State FE No No No No Yes Yes
Standard errors clustered by cable system
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1
Table 32: OTA stands for “Over the Air” broadcast stations likes ABC, CBS, Fox, and NBC.
68