American Sociological Review
2016, Vol. 81(4) 696 –719
© American Sociological
Association 2016
DOI: 10.1177/0003122416655340
http://asr.sagepub.com
Profound social and economic changes have
occurred in the U.S. family over the past half
century. For couples marrying for the first time
in the 1960s, approximately 30 percent divorced
within 15 years, and divorce risks are even
higher for couples in more recent marriage
cohorts (Stevenson and Wolfers 2007). A core
unresolved question is how trends in marital
stability relate to changing family and economic
circumstances. Have wives’ greater earnings
power and work experience increased divorce
by reducing the costs of exiting bad marriages?
Are strained household finances associated with
heightened risk of divorce? Or do spouses’ work
and earnings patterns alter marital stability by
conveying signals about whether each partner is
fulfilling the implicit, symbolic, gendered terms
of the marital contract?
Each of these questions expresses a differ-
ent perspective on the link between work,
money, and the risk of divorce. The economic
independence perspective predicts that
marriages will be more likely to dissolve
655340ASRXXX10.1177/0003122416655340American Sociological ReviewKillewald
2016
a
Harvard University
Corresponding Author:
Alexandra Killewald, 436 William James Hall,
Harvard University, 33 Kirkland St., Cambridge,
MA 02138
Money, Work, and Marital
Stability: Assessing Change
in the Gendered Determinants
of Divorce
Alexandra Killewald
a
Abstract
Despite a large literature investigating how spouses’ earnings and division of labor relate to their
risk of divorce, findings remain mixed and conclusions elusive. Core unresolved questions
are (1) whether marital stability is primarily associated with the economic gains to marriage or
with the gendered lens through which spouses’ earnings and employment are interpreted and
(2) whether the determinants of marital stability have changed over time. Using data from the
1968 to 2013 waves of the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, I consider how spouses’ division
of labor, their overall financial resources, and a wife’s ability to support herself in the event
of divorce are associated with the risk of divorce, and how these associations have changed
between couples married before and after 1975. Financial considerations—wives’ economic
independence and total household income—are not predictive of divorce in either cohort.
Time use, however, is associated with divorce risk in both cohorts. For marriages formed
after 1975, husbands’ lack of full-time employment is associated with higher risk of divorce,
but neither wives’ full-time employment nor wives’ share of household labor is associated
with divorce risk. Expectations of wives’ homemaking may have eroded, but the husband
breadwinner norm persists.
Keywords
divorce, family, gender, earnings, working life
Killewald 697
when the costs of exiting the marriage are low.
The financial strain perspective argues that
limited financial resources stress marriages
and increase the risk of divorce. The gendered
institution perspective suggests that marriages
will be more stable when spouses conform to
the gendered expectations of husbands and
wives. The financial strain and economic
independence perspectives suggest that mate-
rial circumstances, within married couples
and in the event of divorce, respectively, shape
marital stability. The gendered institution per-
spective, by contrast, suggests that money and
work have implications for marital stability
primarily because of their symbolic content.
Given dramatic changes over the second half
of the twentieth century in women’s employ-
ment, education, household labor time, mar-
riage timing, divorce rates, and gender role
attitudes (Bianchi et al. 2012; Fitch and Ruggles
2000; Goldin 2006; Stevenson and Wolfers
2007; Thornton and Young-DeMarco 2001), the
circumstances that hold marriages together or
pull them apart may have changed substantially
during this period. I hypothesize that the effects
of financial characteristics—economic inde-
pendence and financial strain—on divorce risk
are likely to remain stable across time. How-
ever, I hypothesize that the gendered expecta-
tions of spouses have changed across marital
cohorts, with the result that behaviors perceived
as deviant in earlier cohorts may be normalized
in later cohorts. In particular, I predict that the
wife homemaker norm has become less impor-
tant for marital stability, while the husband
breadwinner norm has remained strong. Evalu-
ating change across marriage cohorts in the
determinants of marital stability recognizes that
marriage and its associated expectations for
spouses are embedded in broader, evolving gen-
der structures (Risman 2011).
Despite considerable research, empirical
support for the various perspectives linking
money and work to divorce has been character-
ized as “inconclusive” (Sayer and Bianchi
2000:910), “contradictory” (Dechter 1992:1),
“mixed” (Brines and Joyner 1999:338; Oppen-
heimer 1997:442; South 2001:226), and
“inconsistent” (Ono 1998:675; Sayer et al.
2011:1990), and conclusions regarding these
associations as “elusive” (Rogers 2004:59).
1
The difficulty adjudicating among competing
perspectives is in part due to the challenge of
separately measuring each. Wives’ economic
independence is often measured with either
wives’ earnings or their employment, which are
also measures of households’ financial strain
and conformity to a gender-traditional division
of labor. I instead construct a measure of wives’
economic independence based on the economic
well-being of divorced peers, allowing me to
distinguish among the competing theories of
marital stability.
THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
Conceptually, divorce occurs when at least
one partner believes she will be better off
divorced than remaining married; the risk of
divorce depends on the gains from marriage
(Becker, Landes, and Michael 1977). The
economic independence perspective hypoth-
esizes that divorce rates increase when part-
ners depend less on marriage financially,
allowing spouses to exit unhappy marriages
(Ruggles 1997; Sayer et al. 2011; Schoen
et al. 2002). Wives are likely to be more eco-
nomically dependent on their husbands when
they have accumulated less work experience,
but economic independence also depends on
other aspects of women’s earnings potential,
such as education and occupation, as well as
factors such as child support policies or gov-
ernment support to low-income families. Evi-
dence for the economic independence
perspective for couples in the United States is
mixed, with some scholars finding support
(Dechter 1992; Heckert, Nowak, and Snyder
1998; Ruggles 1997; Sayer et al. 2011;
Schoen et al. 2002; South 2001; Teachman
2010) and others not (Rogers and DeBoer
2001; Sayer and Bianchi 2000). Although it
has received less attention, the economic
independence perspective suggests that men’s
divorce decisions are likewise affected by
their expected economic well-being in the
event of divorce (noted in Sayer et al.
2011:1987).
A second perspective suggests that the cur-
rent income of both spouses stabilizes
698 American Sociological Review 81(4)
marriages by reducing financial strain (Brines
and Joyner 1999; Dechter 1992), for example,
by allowing couples to outsource household
labor, reduce conflict, and increase leisure
time. Through this pathway, wives’ income
may reduce divorce risk, especially when
husbands’ earnings are low (Ono 1998). There
is some evidence that the risk of divorce is
higher for low-income couples (Brines and
Joyner 1999; Dechter 1992), but others find
no such association (Heckert et al. 1998; Sch-
oen et al. 2002; Tzeng and Mare 1995).
The economic independence perspective is
gendered in its implications, because wives
depend more on marriage for their financial
well-being, on average. Yet neither it nor the
financial strain perspective suggests that a
gendered interpretation of spouses’ earnings,
housework, or employment shapes marital
stability. In other words, given the economic
independence of two spouses and their house-
hold income, the preceding perspectives do
not suggest that the risk of divorce depends
on knowing which value belongs to which
spouse.
The gendered institution perspective, by
contrast, predicts that divorce is more likely
when spouses’ employment and earnings vio-
late gendered norms of behavior (Sayer et al.
2011). This is a cultural rather than purely
economic perspective; it draws on the logic of
“doing gender,” in which time in paid and
unpaid labor does not simply produce a pay-
check or clean home, but is a way that indi-
viduals produce and enact gender (Berk 1985;
West and Zimmerman 1987). The gendered
institution perspective is fundamentally dis-
tinct from the economic independence and
financial strain perspectives, because it theo-
rizes divorce as determined by work and
money not because of their financial implica-
tions, but because of the symbolic lens
through which they are interpreted and, spe-
cifically, whether they conform to the gen-
dered expectations of what it means to be a
good wife or a good husband.
Of course, what work behaviors or earnings
outcomes are considered gender-conforming
or gender-deviant is likely to change over
time (Risman 2011)—a point I discuss in
more detail in the next section. Thus, there is
no single test of the gendered institution per-
spective, which may take multiple forms. One
possibility is that wives’ employment is non-
normative. Some scholars have found a posi-
tive association between wives’ employment
and the risk of divorce in the United States
(Brines and Joyner 1999; South 2001; Spitze
and South 1985; Tzeng 1992), but others not
(Schoen, Rogers, and Amato 2006), or only
for couples in unhappy marriages (Sayer et al.
2011; Schoen et al. 2002).
Prior research on the determinants of
divorce disproportionately focuses on the
implications of wives’ employment and earn-
ings. But gendered expectations of men’s
labor affect marriages, too. Wage-earning
remains highly normative for married men
(Nock 1998), and men’s employment, earn-
ings, and economic potential are positively
associated with marriage formation (Oppen-
heimer, Kalmijn, and Lim 1997; Sweeney
2002; Xie et al. 2003) and stability (Ono
1998; Ruggles 1997; Sayer et al. 2011;
Schoen et al. 2002; Tzeng 1992). Beyond any
effects via financial strain, the gendered insti-
tution perspective hypothesizes that hus-
bands’ unemployment strains marriages by
violating the implicit terms of the marital
contract (Cherlin 1979).
In the domain of unpaid labor, the doing
gender perspective suggests that the perfor-
mance of housework is part of the production
of gender for women, and its avoidance is
associated with the production of masculinity.
Wives continue to perform the majority of
housework and childcare (Bianchi et al. 2012)
and to perceive that ultimate responsibility
for its completion falls to them (Hochschild
1989; Stone 2007). This suggests that mar-
riages are more stable when wives spend
more time in household labor and husbands
less. By contrast, Cooke (2006) finds that, in
the United States, a larger share of housework
done by the husband is associated with
increases in marital stability for all but the
most nontraditional divisions of unpaid labor.
In summary, I consider three possible man-
ifestations of the gendered institution perspec-
tive, with each behavior potentially decreasing
Killewald 699
the risk of divorce: wife’s nonemployment or
less than full-time employment, husband’s
full-time employment, and wife’s share of
household labor.
Other scholars sometimes use wives’ rela-
tive earnings, or whether the wife earns more
than her husband, as measures of the gendered
institution perspective, with some finding that
marriages in which wives earn more than half
the income are less stable (Bertrand, Kamen-
ica, and Pan 2015; Heckert et al. 1998; Teach-
man 2010), but others not (Schoen et al. 2002).
One challenge of this approach is that female-
breadwinner couples include both dual-earner
couples, in which she out-earns him, and
couples in which the wife is employed but not
the husband. These two types of couples may
be very different in financial circumstances
and the stability of the wife-breadwinner sta-
tus. Furthermore, the marital stability of the
latter group is affected both by wife-breadwinner
status and husband nonemployment. For sim-
plicity, I focus on employment status in the
main analyses. Supplementary analyses, dis-
cussed following the main results, show no
evidence that spouses’ relative earnings are
associated with the risk of divorce, net of
spouses’ employment statuses.
Change in Marriage Foundations
over Time
Marriage is a social institution, and thus both
rates of marital stability and its determinants
may vary across time and place. In the United
States, over the second half of the twentieth
century, women’s college completion rates
caught and passed those of men, their labor
force participation increased dramatically, and
the gender earnings gap among full-time work-
ers narrowed (Goldin 2006). At home, wives’
average time in unpaid labor declined substan-
tially (Bianchi et al. 2012). Couples married
later and were more likely to divorce (Fitch
and Ruggles 2000; Stevenson and Wolfers
2007), women’s earnings became positively
associated with marriage formation (Sweeney
2002), and gender role attitudes became more
egalitarian ( Thornton and Young-DeMarco
2001).
What are the likely implications of these
changes for the associations between the risk
of divorce and spouses’ labor, income, and
economic independence? I do not hypothe-
size any change in the importance of wives’
economic independence or financial strain.
Wives’ greater labor supply and education
among later marriage cohorts may increase
their economic independence, but there is no
reason to think that the consequences of these
economic factors have changed.
However, I hypothesize that changes in the
social and economic context in which mar-
riages take place have changed the terms of
the marital contract, changing the gendered
lens through which spouses’ labor is inter-
preted. Risman (2011:19–20) argues that each
society’s gender structure “shape[s] the social
roles women and men are expected to follow,
what ‘doing’ gender means in any given inter-
actional encounter, and how marriage is
understood and defined.” What it means to
“do gender” is therefore context-specific
(Cooke 2006). The last half-century was a
time of changing gender structures, suggest-
ing that the ways paid and unpaid labor contri-
butions to marriage by husbands and wives
are interpreted may have changed. For con-
temporary U.S. couples, the husband-bread-
winner/wife-homemaker household may be
neither economically strategic nor preferred
(Oppenheimer 1997; Sayer and Bianchi 2000;
Sayer et al. 2011). As women’s paid work
lives come to resemble men’s, wives’ partici-
pation in full-time paid labor may be one way
contemporary couples “undo” gender ( Risman
2011). For contemporary couples, wives’ full-
time employment is not rare, is not expected
to be inconsistent with gendered norms of
marriage, and is not expected to increase the
risk of divorce. For earlier marriage cohorts,
when wives’ employment was less common, it
is expected to increase the risk of divorce.
Couples’ division of unpaid labor has also
changed. In 2009 to 2010, wives’ average
time in housework was 1.7 times that of hus-
bands, compared to 3.9 times as much in
1975 (Bianchi et al. 2012). I expect that hus-
bands’ housework participation, like wives’
employment, has become more normative in
700 American Sociological Review 81(4)
recent marriage cohorts. For marriages
formed in recent decades, I expect that wives’
higher share of housework is not associated
with greater marital stability. In earlier
cohorts, however, I hypothesize that mar-
riages are more stable when the wife per-
forms a greater share of household labor.
Even in recent marriage cohorts, marriage
remains a gendered institution. As Sayer and
colleagues (2011) note, the male-breadwinner
norm has been more durable than the female-
homemaker norm. Focusing on the effects of
women’s behavior thus risks overlooking the
ongoing symbolic value of men’s employ-
ment for marital stability. Men’s economic
circumstances remain crucial for marriage
formation (Oppenheimer et al. 1997; Sweeney
2002; Xie et al. 2003), and I hypothesize that
men’s employment similarly remains impor-
tant for marital stability.
In summary, I expect that the male-bread-
winner norm has remained, and the female-
homemaker norm has eroded. For recent
marriage cohorts, I expect that husbands’
full-time employment remains positively
associated with marital stability, but wives’
full-time employment and responsibility for
household labor are not determinants of
divorce. For earlier marriage cohorts, I expect
that a gender-traditional division of labor,
with husbands spending time in paid labor but
not unpaid labor, and the reverse for wives, is
associated with greater marital stability.
Little research tests how the economic
determinants of divorce have changed across
marriage cohorts. In a sample of Dutch cou-
ples, Poortman and Kalmijn (2002) compare
couples married 1943 to 1970 versus 1971 to
1997 and find that wives’ employment is desta-
bilizing only in the earlier cohort, and a more
equal division of childrearing has become
more important for marital stability in recent
cohorts. By contrast, the positive association
between husbands’ employment and marital
stability did not decline across cohorts. On the
other hand, South (2001), using data on U.S.
couples from the Panel Study of Income
Dynamics (PSID), finds that wives’ employ-
ment is increasingly positively associated with
marital instability between 1969 and 1992.
Schwartz and Gonalons-Pons (forthcoming)
find that wives’ earnings relative to their hus-
bands’, and especially wives out-earning their
husbands, are positively associated with
divorce for couples marrying in the late 1960s
and 1970s, but not for couples marrying in the
1990s. I revisit the question of change across
marriage cohorts in the economic and time use
determinants of divorce after making several
improvements to the analytic approach.
An Empirical Challenge: Measuring
Economic Independence
Evaluating the economic independence,
financial strain, and gendered institution per-
spectives depends on developing measures
and tests that can distinguish among them. A
key obstacle is that economic independence
cannot be observed directly. Individuals are
more economically independent when their
financial well-being depends less on mar-
riage, which means that the gap between their
financial well-being in marriage versus in the
event of divorce is smaller. However, post-
divorce financial well-being is observed only
for couples who divorce. Therefore, every
attempt to evaluate the economic indepen-
dence perspective requires some decision
about how to approximate the missing value
for couples not observed to divorce.
The most common approximation of a wife’s
economic independence is her current earnings
(absolute or relative to her husband’s) (Heckert
et al. 1998; Rogers 2004; Sayer and Bianchi
2000; Teachman 2010) or employment (Sayer
et al. 2011; Schoen et al. 2002; South 2001).
These proxies, however, measure within-mar-
riage circumstances rather than the expected
costs of divorce—a particularly important limi-
tation given average increases in women’s earn-
ings and employment following divorce
( Tamborini, Iams, and Reznik 2012).
Furthermore, wives’ current employment and
earnings also measure economic resources and
the division of labor within the married house-
hold, requiring additional assumptions to distin-
guish the effects of economic independence
Killewald 701
from those of the financial strain or gendered
institution perspectives. Some scholars attempt
to distinguish between perspectives based on the
sign and shape of the association between wives’
earnings and their risk of divorce (e.g., Rogers
2004), but there is no consensus about which
functional form supports each theoretical per-
spective. Particular points of debate are whether
wives’ independence should be measured with
relative or absolute earnings and whether equal
earnings between spouses indicates mutual
dependence or maximum independence (see the
discussion in Oppenheimer 1997).
An alternative argument is that, if marital
quality moderates the association between
wives’ earnings or employment and divorce,
this supports the economic independence per-
spective, because under this perspective only
bad marriages are at risk of dissolution due to
wives’ economic resources (Sayer et al. 2011;
Schoen et al. 2002). But any determinants of
divorce should matter more for low-quality
marriages, which are closer to the threshold
for divorce. Several studies exploit informa-
tion on which spouse initiated the divorce,
arguing that wives’ economic independence
should particularly encourage wife-initiated
divorces (Rogers 2004; Sayer et al. 2011).
However, wives’ employment might dispro-
portionately increase wife-initiated divorces
not because it increases wives’ economic
independence, but for other reasons, such as
because it increases conflict over household
labor that disproportionately affects wives. I
directly model wives’ predicted post-divorce
economic well-being, making it possible to
distinguish economic independence from
other perspectives. Dechter (1992) uses a
similar strategy, but evaluates a smaller range
of alternative mechanisms.
The first column of Table 1 lists the vari-
ous theoretical perspectives, and the second
column summarizes the claims associated
with each. The key measures associated with
each theory, shown in the third column, are
discussed in detail in the Data section. The
fourth column lists my prediction of whether
a given association has changed across mar-
riage cohorts.
DATA
I model couples’ log odds of divorce using
discrete-time hazard models and data from
couples in the 1968 to 2013 waves of the Panel
Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) (Panel
Study of Income Dynamics 2015), which is
frequently used to study divorce (Brines and
Joyner 1999; Cooke 2006; Dechter 1992;
Heckert et al. 1998; Ono 1998; South 2001). In
1968, the PSID sampled approximately 5,000
U.S. households; it has subsequently collected
information on members of these households
and their descendants annually or biennially. I
restrict my sample to different-sex, married,
head-wife pairs in the PSID, both spouses age
18 to 55, with neither spouse previously mar-
ried. Details of the identification of remarried
couples, marriage start and end dates, and
cohabiting couples are provided in the online
supplement (http://asr.sagepub.com/supple-
mental). I exclude cohabiting and same-sex
couples because of insufficient sample size. I
exclude remarriages because their stability may
follow a different social process. The results of
models including remarried couples are shown
in the online supplement. Couples missing
information on the start or end date of their
marriage are dropped from the sample (227
couples, or 2 percent of the sample). The ana-
lytic sample includes 6,309 couples, of whom
1,684 are observed to divorce or permanently
separate. I apply sample weights, normalized to
one in each survey year, to all analyses.
The choice of a dividing line separating
“early” and “late” marriage cohorts is of
course subject to debate. Goldin (2006) marks
the late 1970s as the beginning of “the quiet
revolution,” when young women began to
accurately predict high labor force participa-
tion and plan for it, including investments in
college education and a career identity. Thus,
particularly for evaluating changing associa-
tions between wives’ employment and the risk
of divorce, 1975 is a reasonable dividing line.
Separating marriage cohorts in this fashion
reflects that change over time in the U.S. fam-
ily has not happened in a smooth, linear way,
but in successive stages.
702 American Sociological Review 81(4)
I allow marriage cohort to moderate all inde-
pendent variables in the divorce risk model,
dividing marriages by whether they occurred
prior to 1975. For ease of interpretation, I pre-
sent separate results for each cohort and indicate
whether the difference in associations between
the cohorts is statistically significant. Results
from models with alternative cutpoints at 1980
and 1985 are shown in the online supplement.
Divorced Women’s Economic
Well-Being: IPUMS Sample
I estimate ordinary least squares models of
economic well-being for divorced and sepa-
rated women age 18 to 55, using data from the
Integrated Public Use Microdata Series
(IPUMS), specifically, samples from the 1970
to 2000 decennial censuses and the 2005 to
2009, 2006 to 2010, and 2008 to 2012 five-year
files of the American Community Survey
(Ruggles et al. 2015). Each sample generates a
unique economic well-being equation for
divorced and separated women. I then apply the
estimated equations to married women in my
PSID sample to estimate their expected eco-
nomic well-being in the next year, were they to
divorce, based on their current characteristics
(incrementing age of the woman and her chil-
dren by one). Predicted post-divorce outcomes
for PSID wives are linear interpolations of the
predicted values based on the equations of the
two adjacent IPUMS years.
Because divorce timing is unknown in most
of the IPUMS samples, I include all currently
divorced and separated women in these mod-
els, although my goal is to estimate likely out-
comes immediately following divorce. This
may lead to biased estimates of women’s likely
outcomes immediately following divorce, if the
well-being of divorced women evolves in the
years following divorce in ways not captured
by the covariates, or if women who remain
divorced rather than remarrying have different
economic outcomes, net of covariates. I return
to this possibility following the main results.
Post-divorce economic well-being.
The outcome in the IPUMS models is the
divorced or separated woman’s economic
well-being, defined as her annual household
income from all sources, divided by the
square root of the number of family members
in the household. Economic well-being is top-
and bottom-coded at the 99th and 1st percen-
tiles of the year-specific distribution.
Human capital. Education and age are
strongly associated with earnings. I allow both
to predict divorced women’s economic well-
being, using interaction terms to allow different
age profiles by education (Heckman, Lochner,
Table 1. Theoretical Perspectives, Measures, and Hypotheses
Theory
Claim: Marriages
Are More Stable
When…
Key Independent
Variables
Hypothesized
Change across
Cohorts
Economic
independence
…spouses’ predicted
financial losses from
divorce are larger
Difference between couple’s
current economic well-being
and wife’s predicted post-
divorce economic well-being
No change
Financial strain … couples have high
economic well-being
Couple’s current economic
well-being
No change
Gendered institution /
wife employment
…wives are not employed
full-time
Dummy variable for full-time
wife employment
Weaken
Gendered institution /
husband employment
… husbands are em-
ployed full-time
Dummy variable for full-time
husband employment
No change
Gendered institution /
housework
…wives do a greater share
of household labor
Proportion of couple’s total
housework performed by the
wife
Weaken
Killewald 703
and Todd 2006). Education is specified in five
categories: (1) less than a high school degree
(less than 12 years of education); (2) a high
school degree but no college (exactly 12 years
of education); (3) some college but no bache-
lors degree (13 to 15 years of education); (4) a
bachelors degree (16 years of education); and
(5) some graduate education (more than 16
years of education). Age is included as a quad-
ratic. A dummy variable is also included for
whether the woman is currently a student,
based on her labor force status.
I also include three-digit 1990 occupation
and industry codes for the woman’s current
main job.
2
These variables are assumed to
affect the risk of divorce only through their
association with economic independence. If
the model of divorced women’s economic
well-being included only variables also
included in the model of the risk of divorce,
the economic independence measure would be
a linear combination of other covariates, mak-
ing it perfectly collinear with the other predic-
tors of divorce. As a result, I could not estimate
its unique association with the risk of divorce.
Family. To adjust for the negative associ-
ation between children and women’s wages
(Budig and England 2001), I include the
woman’s number of biological, step, or
adopted children in the household, separated
by whether they are under age 5, both top-
coded at four.
Demographic traits. I include the wom-
an’s race (Hispanic, non-Hispanic African
American, non-Hispanic white, and other
non-Hispanic), whether she is foreign-born,
region of residence, and whether she has a
health condition that limits the type or amount
of work she can do.
3
All variables except
occupation and industry are interacted with
race; even in the large IPUMS samples, some
occupation and industry categories are too
small for race-specific models.
Risk of Divorce: PSID Sample
Divorce. The outcome is whether a cou-
ple’s marriage terminates with divorce or
separation in the following year. In the biennial
period, divorce is allowed in either of the next
two years, and an offset in the hazard model
adjusts for the difference in exposure time.
Current economic well-being. Finan-
cial well-being is defined as total family
income in the prior calendar year, divided by
the square root of the number of family mem-
bers in the household.
4
Predicted financial consequences of
divorce. To measure economic dependence,
I take the difference between the married cou-
ple’s current economic well-being and the
wife’s predicted economic well-being in the
next year, were she to divorce, based on the
coefficients from the IPUMS models. If not
currently employed, I use the wife’s most
recent occupation and industry to predict her
post-divorce economic well-being.
Gendered institution / husband and
wife employment. For each spouse, full-
time employment (at least 1,500 hours) in the
prior calendar year is measured with an indi-
cator variable. For example, I use employment
from 1985, reported in survey year 1986, to
predict marital dissolution in 1987. The lag in
employment measures (which also applies to
the current economic well-being measure) is
important given prior evidence that wives’
employment and income are endogenous to
unhappiness in marriage (Rogers 1999; Rog-
ers and DeBoer 2001; Schoen et al. 2006).
Gendered institution / housework. I
constructed the share of the couple’s house-
work performed by the wife based on reports of
typical weekly hours of housework for each
spouse. Because housework hours were not
asked in 1968 to 1975 or in 1982, I rely entirely
on multiply imputed values for these years. The
results of a model estimated only on complete
cases are shown in the online supplement.
To reduce the possibility of omitted varia-
ble bias, I include a relevant set of control
variables. I control for a quadratic in the dura-
tion of the marriage in years, accounting for
higher marital stability later in marriage
704 American Sociological Review 81(4)
(Brines and Joyner 1999; Heckert et al. 1998;
Rogers 2004; Sayer and Bianchi 2000; Sayer
et al. 2011; Schoen et al. 2002; Schoen et al.
2006; Smock, Manning, and Gupta 1999;
South 2001). Given prior evidence that Afri-
can American couples experience higher rates
of marital disruption (Brines and Joyner
1999; Heckert et al. 1998; Ono 1998; Schoen
et al. 2006; Smock et al. 1999; Tzeng and
Mare 1995; Tzeng 1992), I control for the
wife’s race using the same categories as in the
IPUMS models.
5
I also include a binary vari-
able for whether the wife is foreign-born,
which in the PSID is approximated by where
she reports having grown up.
To reflect the stabilizing effect of spouses’
education (Cooke 2006; Rogers 2004; Schoen
et al. 2002; Schoen et al. 2006; Smock et al.
1999; South 2001; Teachman 2002, 2010;
Tzeng and Mare 1995), I include controls for
each spouse’s educational attainment, using
the same categories as in the IPUMS models.
I also include a binary variable for whether
the wife is currently a student, measured by
her labor force status.
Premarital fertility (Teachman 2002;
Tzeng and Mare 1995; Tzeng 1992), premari-
tal cohabitation (Schoen et al. 2002; Teach-
man 2002, 2010), and younger age at marriage
(Brines and Joyner 1999; Heckert et al. 1998;
Ono 1998; Sayer and Bianchi 2000; Sayer
et al. 2011; Schoen et al. 2002; Schoen et al.
2006; Smock et al. 1999; South 2001; Tzeng
and Mare 1995; Tzeng 1992) are associated
with increased risk of divorce. I include four
indicator variables set to one: (1) if either
spouse became a parent prior to marriage; (2)
if either spouse was under age 21 at marriage;
(3) if either spouse was under age 25 at mar-
riage; and (4) if the couple cohabited prior to
marriage. Cohabitation is not retrospectively
reported, so spouses are considered to have
cohabited prior to marriage if they were
observed as a cohabiting pair in a survey
wave before the year of their marriage. Thus,
the measure disproportionately excludes
short-term cohabitations and excludes all
cohabiting experiences of couples married
prior to 1968, when data collection began.
Shared assets, including homeownership
(Cooke 2006; Ono 1998; South 2001; Spitze
and South 1985) and children (Ono 1998;
Schoen et al. 2002; Schoen et al. 2006;
Teachman 2010; Tzeng and Mare 1995;
Tzeng 1992), are associated with heightened
marital stability. I measure homeownership
with a dummy variable. I include two varia-
bles capturing the number of children related
to either spouse in the household, separated
by whether they are under age 5, each top-
coded at 4.
I account for variation in divorce rates by
religion (Teachman 2002, 2010) using three
categories: (1) both spouses are Catholic; (2)
at least one spouse reports no religion; and (3)
all other. I also control for region (Northeast,
North Central, South, and West). Observa-
tions from couples currently living outside
the United States are dropped. For each
spouse, I include an indicator variable set to
one if in the present year the person has a
health limitation that affects the amount or
kind of work one can do. I measure the year
of marriage with a series of five-year inter-
vals, to allow a flexible, nonlinear association
between marriage cohort and the risk of
divorce.
As described previously, I exclude the
wife’s occupation and industry from the model
of the risk of divorce, so that the economic
independence measure is not perfectly col-
linear with other variables in the divorce
model. However, this is inappropriate if these
variables affect divorce risk through processes
other than economic independence. To address
one possible pathway, I include the percent of
the wife’s occupation and industry that are
female, as a proxy for the availability of alter-
native partners in the workplace (McKinnish
2007). I calculate the percent female in each
occupation and industry using the IPUMS
data, projecting forward one year as in the
measures of economic independence and lin-
early interpolating between IPUMS years.
All variables in the model are time-varying,
except race, foreign-born status, cohabitation
and birth prior to marriage, and year and age
at marriage. Race and foreign-born status are
Killewald 705
reported in multiple years, so I use the most
recent available valid report and attribute this
value to all observations from the individual.
To avoid understating the uncertainty in
the estimated association between the pre-
dicted financial consequences of divorce and
the risk of divorce, I calculate standard errors
by bootstrapping the IPUMS datasets with
500 replications, generating 500 distinct
models of divorced women’s economic well-
being, each of which is used to generate a
unique model of the hazard of divorce in a
panel-bootstrapped PSID sample.
6
Standard
errors are clustered at the couple level.
All continuous variables are top- and bottom-
coded at the 99th and 1st percentiles of the
weighted year-specific distributions. Missing
data rates are low for most variables, and
missing data are imputed. Details of the impu-
tation strategy, which includes multiple impu-
tation and the use of reports from adjacent
years, are provided in the online supplement,
along with information on the number of
observations and couples removed from the
sample for various reasons (e.g., age restric-
tions, no marriage history data, or remarried).
RESULTS
Descriptive statistics for the IPUMS samples
and results of the regression models predicting
divorced and separated women’s economic
well-being are shown in the online supple-
ment. Each model explains between 32 and 39
percent of the variation in divorced women’s
economic well-being. Occupation and indus-
try measures—the variables excluded from
the divorce models and used to facilitate sta-
tistical identification of the economic inde-
pendence measure as a distinct predictor—are
important contributors to these models: mod-
els that include all other predictors, but
exclude these, explain only between 22 and 29
percent of the variation in divorced and sepa-
rated women’s economic well-being.
How well do the predicted values match
what PSID women who divorce actually
experience? For the 1,159 women in the PSID
observed through divorce, the correlation
between predicted post-divorce economic
well-being and observed economic well-
being in the first full year (or, when not avail-
able, second year) following divorce is .48.
For comparison, wives’ own pre-divorce
earnings—a common proxy for economic
independence—are slightly less strongly cor-
related with post-divorce outcomes (.46).
Thus, predicted post-divorce economic well-
being is strongly associated with real varia-
tion in women’s post-divorce outcomes,
although it certainly does not explain all
individual-level variation.
The fact that the models do not explain all
the individual-level variation in post-divorce
economic well-being does not automatically
imply that coefficients will be biased toward
zero. However, the disruptive effect of eco-
nomic independence will be underestimated
if economic independence is systematically
underestimated for women who divorce or
systematically overestimated for women who
remain married. The median observed and
predicted outcomes of women who divorce
match fairly closely ($24,282 observed ver-
sus $23,433 predicted). Of course, I do not
know whether the post-divorce outcomes of
women who remain married would have been
less than predicted, but previous research
finds no evidence for selection bias of this
kind (Dechter 1992; Smock et al. 1999).
Table 2 shows descriptive traits of the PSID
sample of married couples by marriage cohort.
The economic well-being of married couples is
similar between cohorts (about $53,000), as is
the expected post-divorce well-being of wives
(around $30,000). As a result, there is little dif-
ference between cohorts in the expected
decline in wives’ financial well-being follow-
ing divorce (around $24,000). Likewise, there
has been little change in husbands’ employ-
ment rates: in both cohorts about 90 percent of
husbands are employed full-time.
Wives’ employment has changed more dra-
matically. In the earlier cohort, only 34 per-
cent of wives were employed full-time,
compared to 48 percent in the later cohort.
The average proportion of a couple’s house-
work performed by the wife declined across
706 American Sociological Review 81(4)
Table 2. PSID Sample Means and Proportions (Standard Deviations)
Married
before 1975
Married in
1975 to 2011
Financial Strain
Economic well-being (family income/sqrt(n)),
2013 dollars
$52,443.39 $54,090.21
($33,719.00) ($41,417.64)
Economic Independence
Wife’s predicted post-divorce well-being, 2013 dollars $29,195.56 $32,260.01
($12,710.79) ($15,545.25)
N = 24,816 N = 30,967
Wife’s economic dependence (current well-being –
predicted well-being)
$25,030.43 $23,060.83
($28,146.26) ($34,423.21)
N = 24,816 N = 30,967
Gendered Institution
Wife employed full-time .34 .48
Husband employed full-time .91 .90
Wife’s proportion of housework .81 .72
(.17) (.19)
N = 20,817 N = 32,448
Controls
Proportion female in wife’s
Most recent occupation .73 .68
(.24) (.23)
N = 25,389 N = 31,339
Most recent industry .62 .61
(.20) (.19)
N = 24,865 N = 31,088
Marital duration 19.13 9.91
(8.75) (7.45)
Religion
Other .67 .62
Both spouses Catholic .23 .22
At least one is not religious .10 .16
Race
Non-Hispanic white .88 .82
Non-Hispanic black .06 .07
Hispanic .05 .09
Other .01 .02
Foreign-born .03 .06
Region
Northeast .24 .23
North Central .31 .28
South .30 .29
West .15 .21
Owns home .83 .71
Children under age 5
Prop. with children under 5 .18 .37
Number among those with children under 5 1.19 1.22
(.42) (.44)
Children age 5 to 17
Prop. with children age 5 to 17 .62 .50
Number among those with children age 5 to 17 1.94 1.76
(.95) (.78)
(continued)
Killewald 707
Married
before 1975
Married in
1975 to 2011
Cohabited before marriage .003 .10
Premarital birth .02 .11
Married under age 21 .60 .27
Married under age 25 .93 .69
Wife’s health limits work .10 .08
Husband’s health limits work .10 .07
Wife’s age 38.88 32.72
(8.93) (8.09)
Husband’s age 41.09 34.41
(9.00) (8.09)
Wife currently enrolled in school .005 .02
Wife’s education
Less than high school .18 .10
High school .49 .32
Some college .17 .25
College .12 .23
Graduate school .05 .10
N = 32,850 N = 33,361
Husband’s education
Less than high school .20 .11
High school .34 .32
Some college .19 .23
College .17 .23
Graduate school .10 .11
N = 33,348
Couples 1,908 4,401
Divorces 381 1,303
Observations 32,853 33,470
Note: Samples include all couples with both spouses in a first marriage, with individual variable
summaries restricted to the subsample not multiply imputed on that variable. Sample size matches
the number of observations given at the bottom of the table unless otherwise noted. All estimates are
weighted using the PSID family weight, normalized to average one in each year.
Table 2. (continued)
cohorts, although relatively modestly, from 81
to 72 percent.
Members of the earlier cohort have, on
average, higher marital durations, older
spouses, and older children. Some of this dis-
parity is likely due to the fact that couples
married prior to 1968 are included in the ear-
lier cohort, although they are not observed in
the first year of their marriage. I retain these
couples in the main analysis to increase statis-
tical power. Because I know the marriage
dates of these couples and can control for
marital duration, their inclusion will introduce
bias only if the proportional odds assumption
is violated—if marital duration moderates the
association between the other independent
variables and the risk of divorce. I return to
consideration of this possibility following the
main results.
Table 3 shows results from models predict-
ing couples’ log odds of divorce. Results for
the pre-1975 marriage cohorts are in the first
column, results for the later cohorts are in the
second column; statistically significant differ-
ences between cohorts in the associations are
marked with asterisks next to the variable
labels. For comparison, results from a pooled
model including all marriage cohorts are
708 American Sociological Review 81(4)
shown in the third column. There is no evi-
dence for either the financial strain or eco-
nomic independence perspective in either
cohort or in the pooled model: coefficients are
not statistically significant, and, for financial
strain, in the opposite direction from the theo-
retical prediction.
7
Thus, I do not find support
for the gender-symmetric, money-based
understandings of marital stability. There is
also no evidence for change in the importance
of these perspectives over time.
Turning to the gendered institution per-
spective, I first evaluate the association
between wives’ full-time employment and the
risk of divorce. In the pooled model, wives’
full-time employment is associated with an
18 percent increase in the odds of divorce
(e
.166
= 1.18), and the association is statisti-
cally significant. In the cohort-specific mod-
els, estimates are less precise and wives’
full-time employment is not statistically sig-
nificantly associated with the risk of divorce
for either cohort. In terms of the point esti-
mates, wives’ full-time employment is associ-
ated with a 31 percent increase in the odds of
divorce in the early cohort, compared to 7
percent in the later cohort. The point esti-
mates are consistent with a decline in the
association between wives’ employment and
divorce risk in more recent cohorts, but the
cross-cohort change is not statistically
significant.
Next, I evaluate whether husbands’ lack of
full-time employment is associated with
heightened risk of divorce. In the pooled
model, couples in which the husband is
employed full-time have 21 percent lower
odds of divorce than couples in which he is
not. In the early cohort, husbands’ full-time
employment is associated with a 9 percent
reduction in the odds of divorce, compared to
a reduction of 25 percent in the later cohort.
The association is statistically significant in
the later but not the earlier cohort, and the
change across cohorts is not statistically sig-
nificant.
8
Consistent with predictions, there is
no evidence that the husband employment
aspect of the gendered institution perspective
has become less important for more recent
marriage cohorts. For both husbands and
wives, the observed associations between
employment and the risk of divorce are net of
effects on household income. Thus, the effect
of employment can be separated from its
financial consequences.
In the domain of unpaid labor, for the ear-
lier cohort, the share of housework done by
the wife is negatively and statistically signifi-
cantly associated with the risk of divorce.
This is consistent with the housework compo-
nent of the gendered institution perspective: a
more traditional division of household labor
is associated with greater marital stability in
the earlier cohort. In the more recent cohort,
however, the association is slightly positive
and not statistically significant. The estimate
in the pooled model is negative but not statis-
tically significant. As predicted, the stabiliz-
ing effect of the wife’s responsibility for
unpaid labor has eroded in the recent cohort,
and the change across cohorts is statistically
significant.
Supplementary analyses show that the
wife’s share of housework is less stabilizing
when wives are employed full-time, although
the variation in the association by employ-
ment status is only statistically significant in
the later cohort. This suggests that, at least
for the later cohort, the effect of wives’
housework burden on marital stability may
depend on whether it is part of a traditional
division of labor between spouses or a “sec-
ond shift” (Hochschild 1989) by full-time
employed wives. More flexible specifica-
tions of the division of housework suggest
that, even in the later cohort, wives’ greater
responsibility for household labor is associ-
ated with greater marital stability at least up
until the point of shared housework responsi-
bility. However, there is suggestive evidence
in the later cohort that husbands’ contribu-
tions to housework at low levels may be sta-
bilizing compared to all housework
responsibility falling to wives.
In summary, the pattern of results suggests
it is the division of labor, either paid or
unpaid, that is associated with the risk of
divorce for couples in both cohorts, not finan-
cial considerations. In the pooled model,
wives’ full-time employment is associated
Killewald 709
Table 3. Logistic Regression of Marital Dissolution, by Marriage Cohort (PSID)
1. Married in
1974 or Earlier
2. Married in
1975 or Later 3. Pooled
Financial Strain
Economic well-being (thousands of $) .014 .002 .003
(.009) (.005) (.004)
OR = 1.014 OR = 1.002 OR = 1.003
Economic Independence
Wife’s economic dependence (thousands of $) −.013 −.001 −.003
(.010) (.005) (.004)
OR = .987 OR = .999 OR = .997
Gendered Institution
Full-time employment
Wife .267 .069 .166
*
(.153) (.088) (.080)
OR = 1.306 OR = 1.071 OR = 1.181
Husband −.097 −.293
**
−.238
*
(.208) (.106) (.094)
OR = .908 OR = .746 OR = .788
Wife’s proportion of housework
*
−1.117
*
.050 −.244
(.463) (.233) (.224)
OR = .327 OR = 1.051 OR = .783
Controls
Marital duration
***
.139
***
−.044
*
−.008
(.041) (.022) (.018)
OR = 1.149 OR = .957 OR = .992
Marital duration-squared
**
−.004
***
.000 −.001
(.001) (.001) (.001)
OR = .996 OR = 1.000 OR = .999
Religion (other omitted)
Both spouses Catholic −.157 −.036 −.085
(.215) (.124) (.108)
OR = .854 OR = .964 OR = .918
At least one spouse is not religious
**
.812
***
.257
*
.395
***
(.176) (.101) (.091)
OR = 2.252 OR = 1.293 OR = 1.485
Wife’s race (non-Hispanic white omitted)
Non-Hispanic black
*
−.497 .152 .001
(.291) (.123) (.109)
OR = .609 OR = 1.164 OR = 1.001
Hispanic −.666 −.177 −.243
(.422) (.179) (.162)
OR = .514 OR = .838 OR = .785
Other −.581 .143 −.024
(.725) (.305) (.266)
OR = .559 OR = 1.154 OR = .976
Wife is foreign-born −.275 −.703
**
−.477
*
(.543) (.249) (.219)
OR = .759 OR = .495 OR = .620
(continued)
710 American Sociological Review 81(4)
1. Married in
1974 or Earlier
2. Married in
1975 or Later 3. Pooled
Home ownership −.061 −.398
***
−.328
***
(.172) (.082) (.071)
OR = .941 OR = .672 OR = .720
Number of children
Under age 5 .200 −.001 .004
(.123) (.062) (.054)
OR = 1.222 OR = .999 OR = 1.004
Age 5 and older .091 .152
**
.108
*
(.080) (.053) (.043)
OR = 1.095 OR = 1.164 OR = 1.114
Premarital cohabitation
*
1.308
**
.251
*
.331
**
(.413) (.120) (.115)
OR = 3.700 OR = 1.285 OR = 1.392
Premarital birth .490 .218 .417
***
(.424) (.117) (.114)
OR = 1.633 OR = 1.244 OR = 1.518
At marriage, at least one spouse
Under age 21 .628
***
.297
**
.434
***
(.181) (.096) (.085)
OR = 1.874 OR = 1.345 OR = 1.543
Under age 25 .666 .246
*
.337
***
(.462) (.105) (.100)
OR = 1.947 OR = 1.279 OR = 1.400
Wife is a student −.434 .373 .358
(.975) (.226) (.214)
OR = .648 OR = 1.453 OR = 1.431
Wife’s education (high school omitted)
Less than high school .191 .153 .113
(.212) (.117) (.104)
OR = 1.211 OR = 1.165 OR = 1.119
Some college .174 −.041 .041
(.200) (.097) (.090)
OR = 1.190 OR = .960 OR = 1.042
College .091 −.345
*
−.216
(.280) (.158) (.143)
OR = 1.096 OR = .708 OR = .806
Graduate school −.242 −.514
*
−.434
*
(.432) (.216) (.190)
OR = .785 OR = .598 OR = .648
Husband’s education (high school omitted)
Less than high school −.285 .032 −.093
(.215) (.116) (.102)
OR = .752 OR = 1.032 OR = .911
Some college −.000 −.168 −.100
(.178) (.108) (.094)
OR = 1.000 OR = .845 OR = .905
Table 3. (continued)
(continued)
Killewald 711
1. Married in
1974 or Earlier
2. Married in
1975 or Later 3. Pooled
College −.170 −.559
***
−.374
**
(.218) (.153) (.121)
OR = .843 OR = .572 OR = .688
Graduate school −.100 −.536
**
−.252
(.294) (.185) (.154)
OR = .905 OR = .585 OR = .777
Health limits work
Wife .104 .109 .091
(.242) (.132) (.115)
OR = 1.109 OR = 1.115 OR = 1.096
Husband .177 .216 .169
(.223) (.127) (.114)
OR = 1.193 OR = 1.241 OR = 1.184
Proportion female in wife’s
Occupation
*
.606 −.300 −.006
(.328) (.189) (.170)
OR = 1.832 OR = .740 OR = .994
Industry −.477 .054 −.145
(.333) (.210) (.173)
OR = .621 OR = 1.055 OR = .865
Region (Northeast omitted)
North Central .183 .037 .067
(.211) (.126) (.109)
OR = 1.200 OR = 1.038 OR = 1.069
South .531
*
.279
*
.324
**
(.228) (.124) (.111)
OR = 1.701 OR = 1.321 OR = 1.382
West .376 .181 .251
*
(.242) (.133) (.116)
OR = 1.456 OR = 1.198 OR = 1.286
Year began first marriage (before 1955 is
reference in Models 1 and 3)
1955 to 1959 .971
**
1.057
***
(.320) (.313)
OR = 2.641 OR = 2.879
1960 to 1965 1.208
***
1.268
***
(.296) (.292)
OR = 3.346 OR = 3.554
1965 to 1969 1.211
***
1.280
***
(.298) (.291)
OR = 3.358 OR = 3.597
1970 to 1974 .834
**
.910
**
(.296) (.289)
OR = 2.302 OR = 2.484
1975 to 1979 (reference category in Model 2) 1.359
***
(.289)
OR = 3.894
(continued)
Table 3. (continued)
712 American Sociological Review 81(4)
with heightened risk of divorce, and hus-
bands’ full-time employment is associated
with greater marital stability. Analyses of
change across cohorts are somewhat limited
by low statistical power. However, the stabi-
lizing association between wives’ share of
household labor and the risk of divorce has
declined significantly across cohorts. By con-
trast, there is no evidence that the stabilizing
role of husbands’ full-time employment has
diminished. Conclusions about changes in the
disruptive effect of wives’ full-time employ-
ment are more speculative; point estimates
are consistent with a decline in the associa-
tion between wives’ full-time work and the
risk of divorce, but the cross-cohort change is
not statistically significant.
To provide context for the magnitude of
these associations, Figure 1 shows the pre-
dicted probabilities of divorce, separately for
each cohort, by the employment status of
each spouse and whether the wife performs
50 or 75 percent of the couple’s housework
(the distribution of household labor is so
skewed that an equal division of housework is
the 10th percentile of the wife’s proportion of
housework). The bars show the predicted
probabilities holding all other covariates at
their cohort-specific sample means. The dif-
ferences between cohorts capture both pure
cohort effects and the changing composition
of married couples across cohorts, including
the fact that the earlier cohort disproportion-
ately includes couples of higher marital
1. Married in
1974 or Earlier
2. Married in
1975 or Later 3. Pooled
1980 to 1984 .244
*
1.610
***
(.120) (.286)
OR = 1.277 OR = 5.003
1985 to 1989 .602
***
1.965
***
(.132) (.293)
OR = 1.825 OR = 7.136
1990 to 1994 .291
*
1.637
***
(.142) (.308)
OR = 1.338 OR = 5.138
1995 to 1999 .559
***
1.918
***
(.147) (.301)
OR = 1.750 OR = 6.804
2000 to 2004 .609
***
1.976
***
(.159) (.316)
OR = 1.839 OR = 7.213
2005 to 2011 .425
*
1.831
***
(.178) (.321)
OR = 1.530 OR = 6.241
Constant
***
−7.476
***
−3.525
***
−5.393
***
(.884) (.393) (.435)
OR = .001 OR = .029 OR = .005
Observations 32,853 33,470 66,323
Note: Models are estimated with the PSID family weight, normalized to average one in each year.
Standard errors are bootstrapped to account for uncertainty in predicted well-being from the IPUMS
models. Significance of change across cohorts is marked next to the variable names.
*
p < .05;
**
p < .01;
***
p < .001 (two-tailed tests).
Table 3. (continued)
Killewald 713
durations. The probability of divorce in a
given year is systematically higher for the
later cohort, regardless of employment status
or housework time.
In the early cohort, for an otherwise typi-
cal couple with a wife employed full-time, the
predicted probability of divorce in the next
year is 1.3 percent, compared to 1.0 percent if
she is not employed full-time. When wives do
only 50 percent of the housework in the early
cohort, the predicted probability of divorce in
the next year is 1.5 percent, compared to 1.1
percent if she does 75 percent. By contrast,
the predicted probability of divorce changes
little with the husband’s employment status
and is 1.0 percent if he is employed full-time
and 1.1 percent if he is not.
In the later cohort, an otherwise typical
couple with a husband not employed full-time
has a 3.3 percent predicted probability of
divorce the following year, compared to 2.5
percent if he is employed full-time. Across
wife’s employment and housework catego-
ries, the predicted probability of divorce var-
ies little for this cohort, ranging from 2.5 to
2.6 percent.
The results for control variables are largely
as expected. For both cohorts, at least one
spouse not identifying with a religion, early
marriage, premarital cohabitation, and living
in the South are all associated with higher
odds of divorce. However, for both non-
religious identification and premarital cohabi-
tation, the association has declined statisti-
cally significantly across cohorts. For the
most recent marriage cohorts, the heightened
divorce risk associated with cohabitation may
have disappeared entirely (Manning and
Cohen 2012), but the cohort range defined
here—marriages after 1974—is likely too
broad to detect this change.
LIMITATIONS AND
ROBUSTNESS OF RESULTS
How Robust Is the Lack of Support
for Economic Independence and
Financial Strain?
I considered the possibility that the lack of
support for the economic independence and
financial strain perspectives was due to
1.1%
1.0%
1.0%
1.3%
1.5%
1.1%
3.3%
2.5%
2.5%
2.6%
2.5%
2.6%
Husband not
employed full-
time
Husband
employed full-
time
Wife not
employed full-
time
Wife employed
full-time
Wife does 50%
of housework
Wife does 75%
of housework
Predicted Probability of Divorce
Marriage before 1975 Marriage in 1975 or later
Figure 1. Predicted Probabilities of Divorce in the Next Year
Note: Probabilities are predicted based on the logistic regression coefficients in Table 3 for a respondent
with all other covariates set to the cohort-specific means. Error bars are 95% confidence intervals,
estimated by calculating the bounds of the confidence interval for the predicted log odds (non-
bootstrapped) and then transforming those bounds to predicted probabilities.
714 American Sociological Review 81(4)
specification error or low statistical power. I
experimented with more flexible specifica-
tions of couples’ economic well-being and the
wife’s economic independence and alternative
measures of these concepts. I allowed finan-
cial strain to interact with economic indepen-
dence, considering that wives’ economic
independence may have different effects
depending on household resources (Ono 1998;
Sayer and Bianchi 2000). To reduce collinear-
ity, I also re-estimated the models excluding
all of the time use and financial variables
except the economic independence measure,
and then excluding all except the financial
strain measure. The models provide no sup-
port for the economic independence or finan-
cial strain perspective in either cohort, with
one exception: in the early cohort, wives’
predicted post-divorce economic well-being
(rather than the difference between current
and predicted post-divorce well-being) was
positively and statistically significantly asso-
ciated with the risk of divorce. (Results for all
alternative specifications described in this sec-
tion are in the online supplement.) I also find
that the wife’s economic dependence is nega-
tively and statistically significantly associated
with the risk of divorce in an early cohort
sample restricted to couples married between
1968 and 1974. Because of the large number
of models estimated, it is expected that some
associations will be statistically significant
just by chance. However, it is possible that, in
earlier marriage cohorts, wives’ ability to sup-
port themselves post-divorce facilitated exit
from unhappy marriages.
I also considered the possibility that long-
term economic prospects, including for remar-
riage, rather than likely economic outcomes
immediately following divorce, may influence
divorce decisions. The Census did not collect
information on individuals’ number of mar-
riages between 1980 and 2008. However, I
performed a supplementary analysis using the
1970, 1980, and 2008 to 2012 IPUMS samples
to estimate wives’ long-term post-divorce eco-
nomic prospects, including the possibility of
remarriage. As in the main models, the eco-
nomic independence measure is not statistically
significantly associated with risk of divorce,
and the coefficient is close to zero.
In addition to the economic independence
and financial strain hypotheses, I considered
the possibility that spouses’ earnings, rather
than their employment, might shape the risk of
divorce for symbolic reasons, as an additional
manifestation of the gendered institution per-
spective. I found no evidence that husbands’
earnings stabilize marriages, net of employ-
ment, and no evidence that spouses’ relative
earnings are associated with the risk of divorce.
It is possible that unmeasured characteris-
tics associated with both the risk of divorce
and women’s post-divorce economic out-
comes have suppressed the association
between economic independence and the risk
of divorce, but prior research finds little evi-
dence for bias of this kind (Dechter 1992;
Smock et al. 1999). An additional limitation,
as previously discussed, is that the IPUMS
sample includes women who have been
divorced for more than one year, whose finan-
cial circumstances may not reflect immediate
post-divorce outcomes.
In summary, the additional analyses show
little support for the economic independence
or financial strain perspectives, although it is
of course possible that omitted variable bias
or measurement error may have artificially
suppressed the associations.
How Robust Are the Time Use
Findings?
As previously noted, spouses may adjust work
behaviors in anticipation of divorce, raising
concerns of reverse causality. Anticipatory
effects of this kind are less likely to explain
the association between husbands’ lack of full-
time employment and the risk of divorce:
there is no reason to expect that husbands
anticipating divorce preemptively quit their
jobs. However, wives anticipating divorce
may increase their paid work hours or decrease
household labor. In both cohorts, average paid
labor hours for wives not employed full-time
are no more than 10 hours per week, leaving
substantial room for anticipatory increases.
Killewald 715
To reduce the possibility for spurious asso-
ciations due to anticipation of divorce, I
repeated the analysis lagging measures of the
key independent variables by an additional
two years. For example, in the main models,
earnings and employment in 1985 are used to
predict divorce in 1987. In the supplemental
models, earnings and employment in 1985 are
used to predict divorce in 1989. The associa-
tions are weaker and not statistically signifi-
cant in these models. One interpretation is
that, in the early cohort, wives’ employment
and low responsibility for household labor
were responses to anticipation of divorce. An
alternative explanation is that it does not take
three to four years for gender-deviant behav-
iors to lead to divorce. Using the same exam-
ple, if a wife became employed full-time in
1985 and the couple divorced in 1987, this
couple would contribute to the association
between wives’ employment and the risk of
divorce in the main models, but not in the
lagged models: the couple would already
have divorced and be censored by the time the
outcome is measured in 1989.
I considered that the results for the early
cohorts may have been biased by including
couples married prior to 1968. As described
previously, because marriage dates are
known, the inclusion of these couples does
not bias results if the proportional odds
assumption holds, but it may bias results if
the association between the key independent
variables and the risk of divorce varies by
marital duration, because the early cohort is
disproportionately composed of couples of
longer marital duration. I performed a sup-
plemental analysis restricting the early cohort
sample to couples whose marriages began in
1968 to 1974. As expected, standard errors
increase, due to the smaller sample size. The
association between wives’ full-time employ-
ment and the risk of divorce is larger in mag-
nitude than in the model that includes couples
married before 1968, but, as in the main
sample, it is not statistically significant. For
the wife’s proportion of housework, the stand-
ard error is larger and the coefficient goes in
the opposite direction. The instability of the
housework coefficient is likely related to the
fact that, as mentioned previously, housework
was not reported in the early years of the
PSID.
I also tested the robustness of results by
experimenting with dividing cohorts at 1980
or 1985 instead of 1975. As expected, the
higher risk of divorce for couples with full-
time employed wives is muted when the
dividing line is set later. The patterns for
housework and husband’s employment are
similar to the main specification. Thus, the
late 1970s may have been a particularly
important time for changes in perceptions of
women’s employment, consistent with Gol-
din’s (2006) argument. However, given the
sample size, especially of the earlier cohort, it
is not possible to determine the exact shape of
the trends across cohorts in the determinants
of divorce, and the PSID is not well-suited to
evaluating changes across earlier marriage
cohorts, such as those of the 1960s versus
early 1970s. In general, future research is
needed to continue to evaluate the possibility
of change across cohorts in the determinants
of divorce.
Of course, omitted variable bias may be
responsible for the observed associations
between spouses’ paid and unpaid labor and
the risk of divorce, or for changes in the asso-
ciations across cohorts. For example, a posi-
tive association between wives’ employment
and the risk of divorce may be due to a joint
association with liberal gender ideology
(Sayer and Bianchi 2000), or other unob-
served characteristics associated with their
risk of divorce.
In summary, it is challenging to assess
whether wives’ employment caused higher risk
of divorce in even the earlier marriage cohorts,
because the association may be due to antici-
patory effects and the estimates are imprecise.
By contrast, the findings in the later cohort,
that wives’ employment and housework are
not associated with the risk of divorce, but
divorce is more likely when husbands are not
employed full-time, are not threatened by these
concerns: the later cohort is not affected by
left-censoring, the results are robust across
716 American Sociological Review 81(4)
different choices of cohort cutpoints, and
anticipatory effects should, if anything, over-
state the destabilizing effect of wives’ full-time
employment and stabilizing effect of wives’
household labor responsibility.
CONCLUSIONS
Previous research on the associations between
money, work, and marital stability has
attempted to determine whether marital sta-
bility is affected by wives’ ability to support
themselves in the event of divorce, couples’
financial resources, the gendered interpreta-
tion of spouses’ work and earnings, or some
combination of all three. By constructing a
measure of economic independence distinct
from wives’ current earnings or employment,
my analytic approach allows a more rigorous
test of the pathways by which spouses’ earn-
ings and employment are associated with
their risks of divorce, distinguishing among
the economic independence, financial strain,
and gendered institution perspectives. At the
same time, no single analysis can provide a
definitive assessment of the association
between spouses’ work, economic circum-
stances, and the risk of divorce. One of the
goals of this article is to articulate the consid-
erable analytic challenges to distinguishing
among perspectives and ascertaining causal
order. By making clear the assumptions
required to distinguish among perspectives
and to evaluate change across cohorts, I hope
to motivate future research that will evaluate
these same associations with alternative sam-
ples or assumptions.
Using a sample of married couples in the
United States observed between 1968 and
2013, I do not find support for the economic
independence or financial strain perspectives.
These findings suggest that material circum-
stances, within marriage or outside of it, are
not key determinants of marital stability. As a
consequence, the results cast doubt on the
claim that increases in divorce rates in the
mid-twentieth century were due to women’s
rising economic independence.
However, I find support for the gendered
institution perspective. Although prior research
on the economic determinants of divorce dis-
proportionately focuses on women’s charac-
teristics, the strongest evidence for the
gendered institution perspective is that, for
marriages begun in 1975 or later, divorce is
more likely when husbands are not employed
full-time. Consistent with my hypotheses,
there is no evidence that this association is
weaker for later than earlier marriage cohorts.
Just as male breadwinning has remained
important for marriage formation (Sweeney
2002), the results here demonstrate its endur-
ing importance for marital stability. The
results are consistent with claims that bread-
winning remains a central component of the
marital contract for husbands (Nock 1998).
It is possible that husbands’ less than full-
time employment is associated with marital
disruption more strongly than wives’, not
because of gendered interpretations of lack
of full-time employment, but because hus-
bands’ part-time employment or nonemploy-
ment is more likely to be involuntary.
Involuntary nonemployment may negatively
affect marriages more strongly than volun-
tary nonemployment, by affecting outcomes
like partners’ mental health. It is not possible
to evaluate this perspective with the current
data, because voluntary specialization by
men in unpaid labor is rare: in 2012, only
about one-fifth of stay-at-home fathers were
home primarily to care for the family
(Livingston 2014). Future research is needed
to explore the experiences of deliberately
nontraditional households, although their rar-
ity illustrates the consistency of the male-
breadwinner norm.
Assessing the association between wives’
employment and the risk of divorce and how
this association may have changed across
marriage cohorts is challenging. When all
marriage cohorts are pooled, wives’ full-time
employment is positively and statistically sig-
nificantly associated with the risk of divorce.
The magnitude of the association is smaller in
more recent cohorts, but the change across
cohorts is not statistically significant, nor is
the association in either of the cohort-specific
models. Furthermore, I cannot rule out the
possibility that the positive association
Killewald 717
between wives’ employment and the risk of
divorce is driven by anticipatory effects. The
results are consistent with change across
cohorts in the gender structure shaping expec-
tations for wives’ employment (Risman
2011), but conclusions about cross-cohort
change must remain speculative.
For unpaid labor, however, I find that the
association between wives’ share of house-
work and the risk of divorce has changed
across cohorts; for marriages founded since
1975, wives’ household labor responsibility is
not linearly associated with greater marital
stability. Supplemental models revealed that,
at least in the more recent cohort, the associa-
tion between wives’ household labor and the
risk of divorce is nonlinear and depends on a
wife’s employment status. This suggests that,
for more recent marriage cohorts, at least
some egalitarianism in the division of house-
work may increase marital stability. More
research is needed to investigate the precise
shape of the relationship between housework
contributions and marital stability for differ-
ent marriage cohorts.
The determinants of marital stability for
modern marriages are thus neither post-gender
nor entirely parallel to those of earlier mar-
riages. In both cohorts, marriage remains a
gendered institution, embedded in the larger
gender structure (Risman 2011), with the
division of labor, not financial resources, the
primary lens through which this gendered
nature is reflected. The differing results by
marital cohort suggest that the determinants
of marital stability are likely to continue to
change in tandem with changes in the broader
gender structure. The fact that, in recent
cohorts, wives’ employment is not associated
with the risk of divorce, while husbands’ lack
of full-time employment remains associated
with marital instability, suggests that changes
in the gender structure may not have pro-
ceeded evenly for men and women; fulfill-
ment of the male-breadwinner role appears to
be equally or more strongly associated with
marital stability in more recent marriage
cohorts. Thus, the results highlight the impor-
tance of incorporating men fully into study of
the effects of gender norms on family life.
Acknowledgments
I am grateful to Ian Lundberg and Cassandra Robertson
for research assistance and to the colleagues, seminar
audiences, and anonymous reviewers who provided valu-
able suggestions on earlier versions of this manuscript.
Funding
This research was supported in part by a grant from the
William F. Milton Fund, Harvard University. The collec-
tion of data used in this study (the Panel Study of Income
Dynamics) was partly supported by the National Insti-
tutes of Health under grant number R01 HD069609 and
the National Science Foundation under award number
1157698.
Notes
1. Throughout, I focus on evidence of the determinants
of divorce for U.S. couples, when possible, because
these determinants may vary across countries, espe-
cially when it comes to the gendered interpretation
of spouses’ paid and unpaid labor time and earnings
(Cooke 2006).
2. IPUMS harmonizes occupation and industry codes
to the classification system used in the 1990 Cen-
sus. The PSID classifies jobs according to the 1970
Census classification system in 1968 to 2001 and
according to the 2000 Census classification sys-
tem in 2003 to 2011. To harmonize the occupation
codes, I use a crosswalk provided by IPUMS to con-
vert all codes to 1990 codes (https://usa.ipums.org/
usa/volii/occ_ind.shtml). No such crosswalk exists
for industry codes, so I downloaded IPUMS data
from the 1970 and 2000 censuses, both of which
also give the 1990 industry codes. I then identified
the 1970 and 2000 codes that corresponded to each
1990 category and created a crosswalk to replicate
the mapping used in the IPUMS datasets.
3. Health limitation is not measured in the ACS sam-
ples and is therefore excluded from the models spe-
cific to those years.
4. The PSID has collected wealth information in too
few years to evaluate whether net worth is associ-
ated with the risk of divorce.
5. The determinants of marital stability may vary by
race (Teachman 2010) and parental status (Dechter
1992). I found no statistically significant variation
in the association between the key independent
variables and the risk of divorce between childless
couples and parents or between African Americans
and whites, for either cohort.
6. Because bootstrapped and non-bootstrapped stan-
dard errors were similar, robustness checks and
other supplemental models do not use bootstrapped
standard errors.
7. A model that examined husbands’ economic inde-
pendence instead of or in addition to wives’ also
found no statistically significant associations.
718 American Sociological Review 81(4)
8. I tested whether husbands’ lack of full-time employ-
ment was particularly disruptive if the wife was
not employed full-time when the husband was last
employed full-time. I also tested whether wives’
full-time employment was less disruptive when the
husband was not employed full-time. Results were
consistent with these perspectives, but not statisti-
cally significant for either cohort.
References
Becker, Gary S., Elisabeth M. Landes, and Robert T.
Michael. 1977. “An Economic Analysis of Marital
Instability.” Journal of Political Economy 85(6):
1141–87.
Berk, Sarah Fenstermaker. 1985. The Gender Factory:
The Apportionment of Work in American Households.
New York: Plenum.
Bertrand, Marianne, Emir Kamenica, and Jessica Pan.
2015. “Gender Identity and Relative Income within
Households.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
130(2):571–614.
Bianchi, Suzanne M., Liana C. Sayer, Melissa A. Milkie,
and John P. Robinson. 2012. “Housework: Who Did,
Does or Will Do It, and How Much Does It Matter?”
Social Forces 91(1):55–63.
Brines, Julie, and Kara Joyner. 1999. “The Ties That
Bind: Principles of Cohesion in Cohabitation
and Marriage.” American Sociological Review
64(3):333–55.
Budig, Michelle J., and Paula England. 2001. “The Wage
Penalty for Motherhood.” American Sociological
Review 66(2):204–225.
Cherlin, Andrew. 1979. “Work Life and Marital Dis-
solution.” Pp. 151–66 in Divorce and Separation:
Context, Causes, and Consequences, edited by G.
Levinger and O. C. Moles. New York: Basic Books.
Cooke, Lynn Prince. 2006. “‘Doing’ Gender in Context:
Household Bargaining and Risk of Divorce in Ger-
many and the United States.” American Journal of
Sociology 112(2):442–72.
Dechter, Aimée R. 1992. “The Effect of Women’s Eco-
nomic Independence on Union Dissolution.” CDE
Working Paper No. 92-28. Center for Demography
and Ecology, University of Wisconsin-Madison,
Madison, WI.
Fitch, Catherine A., and Steven Ruggles. 2000. “His-
torical Trends in Marriage Formation: The United
States 1850–1990.” Pp. 59–88 in The Ties That
Bind: Perspectives on Marriage and Cohabitation,
edited by L. J. Waite, C. Bachrach, M. Hindin, E.
Thomson, and A. Thornton. New York: Aldine de
Gruyter.
Goldin, Claudia. 2006. “The Quiet Revolution That
Transformed Women’s Employment, Education, and
Family.” American Economic Review 96(2):1–21.
Heckert, D. Alex, Thomas C. Nowak, and Kay A. Snyder.
1998. “The Impact of Husbands’ and Wives’ Relative
Earnings on Marital Disruption.” Journal of Mar-
riage and the Family 60(3):690–703.
Heckman, James J., Lance J. Lochner, and Petra E.
Todd. 2006. “Earnings Functions, Rates of Return
and Treatment Effects: The Mincer Equation and
Beyond.” Pp. 307–458 in Handbook of the Econom-
ics of Education, Vol. 1, edited by E. A. Hanushek and
F. Welch. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Hochschild, Arlie. 1989. The Second Shift: Working Parents
and the Revolution at Home. New York: Viking Penguin.
Livingston, Gretchen. 2014. “Growing Number of Dads
Home with the Kids: Biggest Increase among Those
Caring for Family.” Washington, DC: Pew Research
Centers Social and Demographic Trends project.
Manning, Wendy D., and Jessica A. Cohen. 2012. “Pre-
marital Cohabitation and Marital Dissolution: An
Examination of Recent Marriages.” Journal of Mar-
riage and Family 74(2):377–87.
McKinnish, Terra G. 2007. “Sexually Integrated Work-
places and Divorce: Another Form of On-the-Job
Search.” Journal of Human Resources 42(2):331–52.
Nock, Steven L. 1998. Marriage in Men’s Lives. New
York: Oxford University Press.
Ono, Hiromi. 1998. “Husbands’ and Wives’ Resources
and Marital Dissolution.” Journal of Marriage and
the Family 60(3):674–89.
Oppenheimer, Valerie Kincade. 1997. “Women’s
Employment and the Gain to Marriage: The Special-
ization and Trading Model.” Annual Review of Soci-
ology 23:431–53.
Oppenheimer, Valerie Kincade, Matthijs Kalmijn, and
Nelson Lim. 1997. “Men’s Career Development and
Marriage Timing During a Period of Rising Inequal-
ity.” Demography 34(3):311–30.
Panel Study of Income Dynamics. 2015. Public Use
Dataset. Ann Arbor: Survey Research Center, Insti-
tute for Social Research, University of Michigan.
Poortman, Anne-Rigt, and Matthijs Kalmijn. 2002.
“Women’s Labour Market Position and Divorce in
the Netherlands: Evaluating Economic Interpreta-
tions of the Work Effect.” European Journal of Popu-
lation 18(2):175–202.
Risman, Barbara J. 2011. “Gender as Structure or Trump
Card?” Journal of Family Theory & Review 3(1):18–22.
Rogers, Stacy J. 1999. “Wives’ Income and Marital Qual-
ity: Are There Reciprocal Effects?” Journal of Mar-
riage and the Family 61(1):123–32.
Rogers, Stacy J. 2004. “Dollars, Dependency, and Divorce:
Four Perspectives on the Role of Wives’ Income.”
Journal of Marriage and Family 66(1):59–74.
Rogers, Stacy J., and Danelle D. DeBoer. 2001. “Changes
in Wives’ Income: Effects on Marital Happiness, Psy-
chological Well-Being, and the Risk of Divorce.”
Journal of Marriage and Family 63(2):458–72.
Ruggles, Steven. 1997. “The Rise of Divorce and Separa-
tion in the United States, 1880–1990.” Demography
34(4):455–66.
Ruggles, Steven, Katie Genadek, Ronald Goeken, Josiah
Grover, and Matthew Sobek. 2015. “Integrated Pub-
lic Use Microdata Series: Version 6.0 [Machine-
Readable Database].” Minneapolis: University of
Minnesota.
Killewald 719
Sayer, Liana C., and Suzanne M. Bianchi. 2000. “Wom-
en’s Economic Independence and the Probability of
Divorce: A Review and Reexamination.” Journal of
Family Issues 21(7):906–943.
Sayer, Liana C., Paula England, Paul D. Allison, and
Nicole Kangas. 2011. “She Left, He Left: How
Employment and Satisfaction Affect Women’s and
Men’s Decisions to Leave Marriages.” American
Journal of Sociology 116(6):1982–2018.
Schoen, Robert, Nan Marie Astone, Kendra Rothert,
Nicola J. Standish, and Young J. Kim. 2002. “Wom-
en’s Employment, Marital Happiness, and Divorce.”
Social Forces 81(2):643–62.
Schoen, Robert, Stacy J. Rogers, and Paul R. Amato.
2006. “Wives’ Employment and Spouses’ Marital
Happiness: Assessing the Direction of Influence
Using Longitudinal Couple Data.” Journal of Family
Issues 27(4):506–528.
Schwartz, Christine R., and Pilar Gonalons-Pons. Forth-
coming. “Trends in Relative Earnings and Marital
Dissolution: Are Wives Who Outearn Their Husbands
Still More Likely to Divorce?” RSF: The Russell Sage
Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences.
Smock, Pamela J., Wendy D. Manning, and Sanjiv Gupta.
1999. “The Effect of Marriage and Divorce on Wom-
en’s Economic Well-Being.” American Sociological
Review 64(6):794–812.
South, Scott J. 2001. “Time-Dependent Effects of Wives’
Employment on Marital Dissolution.” American
Sociological Review 66(2):226–45.
Spitze, Glenna, and Scott J. South. 1985. “Women’s
Employment, Time Expenditure, and Divorce.” Jour-
nal of Family Issues 6(3):307–329.
Stevenson, Betsey, and Justin Wolfers. 2007. “Marriage
and Divorce: Changes and Their Driving Forces.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(2):27–52.
Stone, Pamela. 2007. Opting Out? Why Women Really
Quit Careers and Head Home. Berkeley: University
of California Press.
Sweeney, Megan M. 2002. “Two Decades of Fam-
ily Change: The Shifting Economic Foundations
of Marriage.” American Sociological Review
67(1):132–47.
Tamborini, Christopher R., Howard M. Iams, and Gayle
L. Reznik. 2012. “Women’s Earnings before and after
Marital Dissolution: Evidence from Longitudinal
Earnings Records Matched to Survey Data.” Journal
of Family and Economic Issues 33(1):69–82.
Teachman, Jay D. 2002. “Stability across Cohorts in
Divorce Risk Factors.” Demography 39(2):331–51.
Teachman, Jay. 2010. “Wives’ Economic Resources
and Risk of Divorce.” Journal of Family Issues
31(10):1305–23.
Thornton, Arland, and Linda Young-DeMarco. 2001. “Four
Decades of Trends in Attitudes toward Family Issues in
the United States: The 1960s through the 1990s.” Jour-
nal of Marriage and Family 63(4):1009–37.
Tzeng, Jessie M., and Robert D. Mare. 1995. “Labor
Market and Socioeconomic Effects on Marital Stabil-
ity.” Social Science Research 24(4):329–51.
Tzeng, Meei-Shenn. 1992. “The Effects of Socioeco-
nomic Heterogamy and Changes on Marital Dissolu-
tion for First Marriages.” Journal of Marriage and
the Family 54(3):609–619.
West, Candace, and Don H. Zimmerman. 1987. “Doing
Gender.” Gender & Society 1(2):125–51.
Xie, Yu, James M. Raymo, Kimberly Goyette, and
Arland Thornton. 2003. “Economic Potential and
Entry into Marriage and Cohabitation.” Demography
40(2):351–67.
Alexandra Killewald is Professor of Sociology at Har-
vard University. Much of her research examines the
mutual relationships between family circumstances and
work outcomes in the United States, emphasizing how
gender shapes these associations and the role of the fam-
ily in social stratification.