MARKETING SCIENCE
Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23
http://pubsonline.informs.org/journal/mksc/ ISSN 0732-2399 (print), ISSN 1526-548X (online)
Match Your Own Price? Self-Matching as a
Retailer’s Multichannel Pricing Strategy
Pavel Kireyev,
a
Vineet Kumar,
b
Elie Ofek
a
a
Harvard Business School, Harvard University, Boston, Massachusetts 02163;
b
Yale School of Management, Yale University, New Haven,
Connecticut 06520
Contact:
Received: July 22, 2015
Revised: June 9, 2016
Accepted: August 9, 2016
Published Online in Articles in Advance:
August 3, 2017
https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2017.1035
Copyright: © 2017 INFORMS
Abstract. Multichannel retailing has created several new strategic choices for retailers.
With respect to pricing, an important decision is whether to oer a “self-matching policy,”
which allows a multichannel retailer to oer the lowest of its online and store prices to con-
sumers. In practice, we observe considerable heterogeneity in self-matching policies: There
are retailers who oer to self-match and retailers who explicitly state that they will not
match prices across channels. Using a game-theoretic model, we investigate the strategic
forces behind the adoption (or non-adoption) of self-matching across a range of compet-
itive scenarios, including a monopolist, two competing multichannel retailers, as well as
a mixed duopoly. Though self-matching can negatively impact a retailer when consumers
pay the lower price, we uncover two novel mechanisms that can make self-matching prof-
itable in a duopoly setting. Specifically, self-matching can dampen competition online
and enable price discrimination in-store. Its eectiveness in these respects depends on
the decision-making stage of consumers and the heterogeneity of their preference for the
online versus store channels. Surprisingly, self-matching strategies can also be profitable
when consumers use “smart” devices to discover online prices in stores. Our findings
provide insights for managers on how and when self-matching can be an eective pricing
strategy.
History:
Preyas Desai served as the editor-in-chief and Dmitri Kuksov served as associate editor for
this article.
Supplemental Material:
The online appendix is available at https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2017.1035.
Keywords:
price self-matching
multichannel retailing
pricing strategy
online shopping
omnichannel
price discrimination
1. Introduction
Many, if not most, major retailers today use a mul-
tichannel business model, i.e., they oer products in
physical stores and online. These channels tend to
attract dierent consumer segments and allow retailers
to cater to distinct buying behaviors and preferences.
Consumers are also becoming more savvy in using
the various channels during the buying process, i.e.,
researching products, evaluating fit, comparing prices,
and purchasing (Neslin et al. 2006, Grewal et al. 2010,
Verhoef et al. 2015).
Retailers must attend to all elements of the market-
ing mix as they strive to maximize profits. Not surpris-
ingly, pricing has always been an important strategic
variable for t hem to “get right. When retailers were
predominantly brick-and-mortar, they had to deter-
mine the most eective store price to set for their mer-
chandise. However, having embraced a multichannel
selling format, pricing decisions have become much
more complex for these retailers to navigate. Not only
do they need to price the products in their physical
stores, they also need to set prices for products in their
online outlets and consider how the prices across the
various channels should relate to one another. This
complexity in devising a comprehensive multichan-
nel pricing strategy is front and center for retailers
today, as evidenced by the myriad commentaries in
the retail trade press. As Forrester Research reports
(Mulpuru 2012), “It is imperative for eBusiness profes-
sionals in retail to adopt cross-channel best practices
including ...pricing.
Formulating an eective multichannel pricing strat-
egy can be challenging. A recent survey of lead-
ing retailers (eMarketer 2013) revealed that their top
two pricing challenges are: (1) increased price sen-
sitivity of consumers, and (2) pricing aggressiveness
from competitors. In a world where many consumers
buy online or conduct research online before enter-
ing a store, these findings suggest that the need to
manage the heightened price sensitivity and combat
intense competition are becoming even more impor-
tant. Interestingly, the above study did not find the
item “need to provide consistency in price across
channels” to be among the top few challenges these
retailers face, underscoring that they feel they have
flexibility in customizing their price to the specific
1
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
2 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
channel and customer mix that chooses to shop there.
Indeed, according to Gartner’s Kevin Sterneckert (Reda
2012, p. 6), “Using a single-channel, consistent pric-
ing strategy misses important opportunities in the
marketplace ... Consistent with these survey obser-
vations, we specifically investigate how retailers can
leverage self-matching across channels to set prices
flexibly to diminish intense price competition.
With a self-matching policy, the retailer commits to
charging consumers the lower of its online and store
prices for the same product when consumers furnish
appropriate evidence of a price dierence. Note that
even though self-matching can provide some degree
of price consistency, it is fundamentally dierent from
committing to consistent prices and setting exactly
the same prices across all channels, as will be clear
in our analysis in Section 4. Commonly, this policy
features store to online self-matching, allowing con-
sumers to pay the typically lower online prices for store
purchases.
1
This policy is a novel marketing instru-
ment t hat is uniquely available to multichannel retail-
ers and not relevant in the single-channel case. The
primary objective of our paper is to understand the
strategic consequences of such self-matching policies.
We note that competitive price-matching policies have
been extensively studied by contrast (and are reviewed
in Section 2).
Examining a number of retail markets, there are two
distinct self-matching patterns that come to our atten-
tion. First, we observe considerable heterogeneity in the
adoption of self-matching policies across retailers in the
United States, including those competing for the same
market. For example, Best Buy, Sears, Staples, Oce
Depot, Toys “R” Us, and PetSmart price match their
online channels in-store, whereas JCPenney, Macy’s,
Urban Outfitters, and Petco explicitly state that they
will not match their prices across channels.
2
Second, we
observe heterogeneity in self-matching across industries.
In consumer electronics and home improvement, major
players oer self-matching, whereas in low-end depart-
ment stores and clothing, most or all retailers tend not
to adopt self-matching.
We aim to develop insights on when to expect dif-
ferent self-matching patterns for multichannel retailers
in a given category, i.e., all self-match, some self-match
while others do not, and none self-match. To this end,
we examine the use of a self-matching pricing policy
by multichannel retailers across a variety of compet-
itive settings, including a monopoly, a duopoly with
two competing multichannel retailers, and a mixed
duopoly in which a multichannel retailer competes
with an e-tailer. More specifically, we address the fol-
lowing research questions:
(1) What strategic mechanisms underpin the deci-
sion to implement a self-matching pricing policy?
(2) When do multichannel retailers choose to self-
match in equilibrium? How do customer and product
characteristics, and the nature of competition, influ-
ence a retailer’s decision to self-match?
(3) How does self-matching aect the prices charged
online and in-store?
(4) Are retailers better or worse o having access to
self-matching as a strategic tool?
To investigate these questions, we develop a model
that allows us to capture the eects of self-matching
on consumer and retailer decisions. We allow for con-
sumer heterogeneity along a number of important
dimensions. These dimensions include consumers’
channel preferences, their stage in the decision-making
process (DMP), and their preference across retailers.
As to channel preferences, we allow for “store-only”
consumers who have a strong preference to purchase
in-store where they can “touch and feel” merchandise
and instantly obtain the product. By contrast, “channel-
agnostic consumers” do not have a strong preference
for any channel from which they purchase. We also
distinguish between consumers who know the exact
product they want to purchase (“Decided”) and con-
sumers who only recognize the need to purchase from
a category and require a store visit to shop around and
find the specific version or model that best fits their
needs (“Undecided”). Finally, consumers have hori-
zontal taste (or brand) preferences across retailers.
Retailers oer unique products of similar value
and are at the ends of a Hotelling linear city, wit h
consumer location on the line indicating retailer pref-
erence. Retailers first choose a self-matching pricing
policy and subsequently and simultaneously set price
levels for store and online channels. We analyze the
subgame perfect equilibria of the game.
Our analysis reveals several underlying mechanisms
that aect the profitability of self-matching in equilib-
rium. The first eect, termed channel arbitrage, is neg-
ative and reduces profits, whereas the other eects
termed decision-stage discrimination and online competi-
tion dampening increase profits. Thus, the overall profit
implications of implementing a self-matching pricing
policy depend on the existence and magnitude of these
eects.
Consider the pricing incentives faced by a mul-
tichannel retailer absent self-matching. In the store
channel, it faces two types of consumers; those who
researched the product online before choosing a store
(decided consumers) and t hose who visit their pre-
ferred store first to identify the product that best
matches their needs (undecided consumers). Retailers
may want to charge a higher price to the latter type,
but are unable to do so because both types purchase in
the store channel. Furthermore, consumers who shop
online tend to be informed of the online prices at both
retailers, which leads to more competitive pricing in
the online channel than in-store.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 3
Now, consider the strategic impact of self-matching
policies. With self-matching, consumers who research
the product online but purchase in-store can redeem
the lower online price; we refer to this profit-reducing
eect as channel arbitrage. However, consumers who
visit their preferred store first without searching online
are unable to obtain evidence of a lower price for their
desired product before arriving at the store. These con-
sumers pay the store price even when a self-matching
policy is in eect, leading to the decision-stage discrim-
ination eect, thus allowing a self-matching retailer to
charge dierent prices to store consumers based on
their decision stage, which can increase profits.
If only one retailer self-matches, decided consumers
can redeem the lower online price at the self-matching
retailer’s store but only have access to the store price at
the rival. This induces the self-matching retailer to set
a higher online price to mitigate the negative impact of
channel arbitrage. The rival follows suit due to strate-
gic complementarity of prices and sets a higher online
price as well, thus softening online competition. We
refer to this profit-increasing mechanism as the online
competition dampening eect, with self-matching serving
as a commitment device to increase online prices from
the purely competitive level. It emerges only when one
of the retailers oers to self-match: If both retailers self-
match, decided consumers have access to the online
prices at both stores, and intense competition in the
online channel ensues.
We also investigate the equilibrium profitability of
the self-matching policy. Our analysis shows that self-
matching is not necessarily harmful. In fact, both re-
tailers can be better o by oering to self-match when the
positive online competition dampening and/or deci-
sion-stage discrimination eects dominate the negative
channel arbitrage eect.
We investigate several model extensions in Section 5.
First, we examine how the presence of consumers
equipped with “smart” devices, who can retrieve
online price information when in the store, aects
retailers’ incentives to implement a self-matching pol-
icy. Intuitively, when more consumers can retrieve the
lower online price, the negative channel arbitrage eect
is more pronounced. However, we find that the pres-
ence of “smart” consumers can allow retailers to ben-
efit even more from online competition dampening by
charging higher online prices. In another extension,
we examine the eects of self-matching in a mixed
duopoly, in which a multichannel retailer competes
with an online-only retailer (i.e., a pure e-tailer). We
find that competition is dampened in the online chan-
nel when the multichannel retailer chooses to self-
match, allowing both retailers to benefit.
Finally, we conducted a consumer survey that allows
us to evaluate how customer and market characteris-
tics pertain to our model setup and findings. We find
evidence of significant consumer heterogeneity on the
dimensions modeled. Mapping the equilibrium pre-
dictions of the model to observed self-matching poli-
cies chosen by firms is suggestive of the relevance of
our approach.
Next, we review the literature (Section 2), describe
the model (Section 3), and analyze equilibrium strate-
gies and outcomes (Section 4). We then consider sev-
eral extensions of the model (Section 5) and conclude
by discussing managerial and empirical implications
as well as future research opportunities (Section 6).
2. Literature Review
We draw from two separate streams of past research.
The first is focused on multichannel retailing, and
the second on competitive price-matching in a sin-
gle channel. Research in multichannel retailing has
typically assumed that retailers set the same or dif-
ferent prices across channels, without examining the
incentives to adopt a self-matching policy. Liu et al.
(2006), for example, study a brick-and-mortar retailer’s
decision to open an online arm, assuming price con-
sistency, or dierent prices across channels. Zhang
(2009) considers separate prices per channel and stud-
ies the retailer’s decision to operate an online arm and
advertise store prices. Ofek et al. (2011) study retail-
ers’ incentives to oer store sales assistance when also
operating an online channel, allowing for identical or
dierent pricing across channels. Aside from ignoring
self-matching pricing policies, this literature has not
considered or modeled heterogeneity in consumers’
DMPs, which plays an important role in their channel
choice in practice.
The key theoretical mechanisms modeling sales and
service were developed by Shin (2007) and investigated
further in the literature (e.g. Mehra et al. 2013). While
"price-matching has been suggested as a strategy to
combat showrooming, to our knowledge, t here has not
been a careful modeling and evaluation of whether and
when such policies can be eective, particularly in a
competitive context.
Competitive price-matching is an area that has been
well studied. This literature has generally focused on
a retailer’s incentives to match competitors’ prices in
a single channel setting, typically brick-and-mortar
stores. Salop (1986) argued that when retailers price
match each other, this leads to higher prices than oth-
erwise, as they no longer have an incentive to engage
in price competition, thus implying a form of tacit
collusion (Zhang 1995). However, competitive price-
matching has also been found to intensify competition
because it encourages consumer search (Chen et al.
2001). Other research in competitive price-matching
has explored its role as a signaling mechanism for cer-
tain aspects of a retailer’s product or service (Moorthy
and Winter 2006, Moorthy and Zhang 2006), the impact
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
4 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
of hassle costs (Hviid and Shaer 1999), interaction
with product assortment decisions (Coughlan and
Shaer 2009), and the impact of product availability
(Nalca et al. 2010).
By contrast, self-matching pricing policies represent a
phenomenon relevant only for multichannel retailers;
recent retailing trends make self-matching an impor-
tant issue to study. First, the nature of competition
is evolving in many categories, from retailers carry-
ing similar products from multiple brands to manu-
facturers who establish their own retail stores, e.g.,
Apple, Microsoft, and Samsung. Second, many retail-
ers are moving towards establishing strong private
label brands or building exclusive product lines to
avoid direct price wars wit h competitors (Bustillo and
Lawton 2009, Mattioli 2011). For instance, 50% or more
of products sold by retailers such as JCPenney or health
supply retailer GNC are exclusive or private label;
electronics retailers such as Brookstone and Best Buy
are also increasingly focused on private label prod-
ucts.
3
These trends accentuate the relevance of self-
matching relative to competitive price-matching as
the product assortments retailers carry become more
dierentiated.
The mechanisms underlying self-matching are also
connected to the broad literature on price discrimina-
tion. Cooper (1986) examines pricing in a two-period
model, where retailers commit to giving consumers
who purchase in the first period the dierence between
the first and second period prices if the latter price
is lower (a form of intertemporal self-matching). The
author shows t hat this policy may increase retailer prof-
its as it reduces the incentive to lower prices in the sec-
ond period for both retailers. This eect is similar to
the online competition dampening eect we identify,
whereby a retailer reduces its own incentive to price
lower online by inducing channel arbitrage through
self-matching. However, whereas both retailers can
oer and benefit from a “most-favored-customer” pol-
icy in the intertemporal setting, the online competition
dampening eect can exist only if one retailer oers
to self-match. If both retailers self-match, they reignite
competition in the online market and nullify the eect.
Cross-channel price-matching is thus driven by dier-
ent strategic incentives.
Thisse and Vives (1988), Holmes (1989), and Corts
(1998) consider cases wherein price discrimination may
lead to lower profits for competing retailers in equi-
librium. Similarly, retailers may be compelled to self-
match in equilibrium even though they would have
been better o had self-matching not been an option.
In our context, on one hand, a self-matching policy
acts as a commitment not to price discriminate decided
consumers across channels, which can lead to greater
profits for both retailers because this creates an incen-
tive to increase the online price to mitigate the arbi-
trage eect. On the other hand, a self-matching policy
enables price discrimination between undecided and
decided consumers who shop in-store. Depending on
the relative sizes of these segments, self-matching poli-
cies may emerge in equilibrium and lead to greater or
lower profits for both retailers.
Desai and Purohit (2004) consider a competitive set-
ting where consumers may haggle over price with
retailers. Some form of haggling may occur in the self-
matching setting if retailers are not explicit about their
policies and consumers must wrangle with managers
to obtain a self-match. This interaction may induce
additional costs for consumers and for retailers when
processing a self-matching policy. In our analysis, we
focus on the case of retailers explicitly announcing
their self-matching policies and illustrate how self-
matching emerges in equilibrium in the absence of con-
sumer haggling or hassle costs. In an extension, we
consider the implications of retailer processing costs
when a consumer redeems a self-match.
3. Model
3.1. Retailers
Two competing retailers in the same category are
situated at the endpoints of a unit consumer inter-
val, or linear city, i.e., x 0 and x 1 (Hotelling
1929). The retailers oer unique and non-overlapping
sets of products. Because they carry dierent prod-
ucts, they do not have the option of oering competi-
tive price-matching guarantees. For example, Gap and
Aeropostale sell apparel and operate in the same cate-
gories, but the items themselves are not the same and
reflect the dedicated designs and logos of each of these
retailers.
We model a two-stage game in which the retailers
must first decide on self-matching policies and then
on prices in each channel. We denote by SM
i
0 t he
decision of retailer i not to self-match and by SM
i
1
the decision to self-match, leading to four possible sub-
games, i.e., (0, 0), (1, 1), (1, 0), and (0, 1) representing
(SM
1
, SM
2
). In each subgame, p
k
j
denotes t he price set
by retailer j 2{1, 2} in channel k 2{on, s}, where on
stands for the online or Internet channel and s stands
for the physical store channel. With self-matching, con-
sumers who retrieve the match pay the lowest of the
two channel prices. In the equilibrium analysis that
follows, we find that retailers never set lower prices in-
store than online. Hence, the only relevant matching
policy to focus on is the store-to-online self-match. All
retailer costs are assumed to be zero.
3.2. Consumers
To capture important features of the shopping process
in multichannel environments, we model consumers as
being heterogeneous along multiple dimensions.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 5
Retailer Brand Preferences: Consumers vary in their
preferences for a retailer’s product, e.g., a consumer
might prefer Macy’s clothing lines to those oered at
JCPenney. We capture this aspect of heterogeneity by
allowing consumers to be distributed uniformly along
a unit line segment in the preference space, x U[0, 1].
A consumer at preference location x incurs a “mis-
fit cost” x when purchasing from retailer 1 and a
cost (1 x) when purchasing from retailer 2. Note
that the parameter does not involve transportation
costs, rather it represents horizontal retailer-consumer
“misfit” costs, which are the same across the online
and store channels. Misfit costs reflect heterogeneity in
taste over dierentiated products of similar value, e.g.,
the collection of suits at Banana Republic compared to
those at J. Crew.
Channel Preferences: Channel-agnostic (A) consumers
do not have an inherent preference for either channel
and, for a given retailer, would buy from whichever
channel has the lower price for the product they pur-
chase. On the other hand, Store-only (S) consumers find
the online channel insucient, e.g., due to waiting
times for online purchases, risks associated with online
purchases (such as product defects), etc. These con-
sumers purchase only in the store, alt hough they might
research products online and obtain online price infor-
mation for the product they plan to buy. We assume
that channel-agnostic consumers form a fraction of
size of the market while store-only consumers form
a fraction of size 1 .
Decision Stage: Consumers can dier in their deci-
sion stage, a particularly important aspect of multi-
channel shopping (Neslin et al. 2006, Mulpuru 2010,
Mohammed 2013). Undecided (U) consumers of propor-
tion (0 <<1) need to go to the store because t hey
do not have a clear idea of the product they wish to
purchase. Decided (D) consumers of proportion 1
are certain about the product they wish to buy and
can thus costlessly search for price information from
home. Undecided consumers first visit a retailer’s store,
selecting the store closest to their preference location,
to find an appropriate product that fits their needs.
After determining fit, they may purchase the product
in-store or return home to purchase online, depending
on their channel preference. Consumers obtain a value
v from purchasing their selected product.
Categories such as apparel, fashion, furniture, and
sporting goods are likely to feature more undecided
consumers, as styles and sizes of products are impor-
tant factors that frequently change. Because undecided
consumers do not know which product they want
before visiting a store, they do not have at their dis-
posal all prices while at the store, since keeping track
of a large number of products, models, and versions
even within a category would be impractical. Unde-
cided consumers in the model are unaware of the
Table 1. Consumer Segments and Proportions
Decision stage
Channel preference Undecided (U) Decided (D)
Store (S) (SU): (1 ) (SD): (1 )(1 )
Agnostic (A) (AU): ⌘ (AD): (1 )
exact product they wish to purchase beforehand (they
have limited ability to infer prices under dierent self-
matching configurations before visiting the store).
4
We set the travel cost for a consumer’s first shopping
trip to zero and assume that additional trips are suf-
ficiently costly. Note that if consumers have no cost to
visit multiple stores in person, then we obtain a trivial
specification wherein there is no distinction between
decided and undecided consumers who shop in-store.
Throughout the paper, we focus on the more interest-
ing case wherein additional shopping trips are costly
enough so that store-only undecided consumers do
not shop across multiple physical stores (see proofs of
Propositions 2 and 4 in the appendix for formal condi-
tions on the travel cost). However, in all cases, decided
consumers research products and prices in advance.
5
Table 1 depicts the dierent consumer segments in-
cluded in the model. We denote the four segments
of consumers as SU, AU, SD, and AD, depending on
their channel preference and decision stage; the size of
each segment is indicated in the corresponding cell of
the table. Each of the four segments is uniformly dis-
tributed on a Hotelling linear city of unit length, such
that consumer location on the line determines retailer
preference. In the online appendix, we present exam-
ples to illustrate the buying process of a consumer
from each segment. Table 2 details the notation used
throughout the paper.
3.3. Sequence of Events
Figure 1 details the sequence of events. First, retailers
simultaneously decide on a self-matching pricing strat-
egy. Then, after observing each other’s self-matching
decisions, they determine the price levels in each chan-
nel. Consumers, depending on their type (decided or
undecided, store or channel-agnostic, and horizontal
preference), decide on which channel and retailer at
which to shop. Decided consumers, who know the
online price before visiting the store, can ask for a
price match if the online price is lower and the retailer
has chosen to self-match. Finally, consumers make pur-
chase decisions and retailer profits are realized.
3.4. Consumer Utility
We now specify the utility consumers derive under
dierent self-matching scenarios. Recall that store-
decided (SD) consumers know all prices across both
retailers and channels before they make a purchase
decision. Channel-agnostic undecided (AU) consumers
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
6 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
Table 2. Summary of Notation
Notation Definition
p
s
j
In-store price for retailer j
p
on
j
Online price for retailer j
SM
j
Retailer j’s self-matching decision
SM
i
, SM
j
j
Retailer j’s total profit in subgame (SM
i
, SM
j
)
Consumer
v Consumer valuation of the product
Retailer dierentiation
1 Fraction of decided segment of consumers
Fraction of undecided segment of consumers
Fraction of channel-agnostic consumers
1 Fraction of store-only consumers
· x for x 2[0 , 1] Measure of retailer preference for consumer
at location x
u
k
j
Utility for purchasing from retailer j
in channel k
have t he option of visiting a store to learn what they
want and then returning home to make an online pur-
chase, whereas store undecided (SU) consumers pur-
chase in the store they first visit or make no purchase.
Consumers obtain zero utility when they do not make
a purchase.
Consider the case when neither retailer self-matches,
i.e., (SM
1
, SM
2
) (0, 0). For a consumer who knows
the product she wishes to purchase, the utility for each
retailer and channel option is as follows:
u
on
1
v p
on
1
x, u
s
1
v p
s
1
x,
u
on
2
v p
on
2
(1 x), u
s
2
v p
s
2
(1 x),
(1)
Figure 1. (Color online) Sequence of Events in t he Model
Consumers make purchase decisions
Simultaneously decide on self-matching policies
Obtain product and price information from all
channel and retailer options
Visit store of retailer with closer match to
preferences to learn about products
Decided consumers Undecided consumers
Channel agnostic Store only Channel agnostic Store only
Retailers R1 and R2
Store: R1 and R2
Obtain self-match if
retailer offers policy
Choice set at purchase time
(channel and retailer)
Store: R1 and R2
Online: R1 and R2
Observing policies, simultaneously
set prices in each channel
Consumers
gather
product and
price
information
1
2
Store: R1 if x <
Online: R1 and R2
Does not obtain price-match
even if retailer offers policy
Store: R1 if x <
R2 o/w
1
2
R2 o/w
,
,
Note. o/w, otherwise.
where v is the value of the product, p
k
1
and p
k
2
(k on or
k s) are the prices set by retailers 1 and 2, respectively,
measures the degree of consumer preferences for
retailers, and x 2[0, 1] is the consumer’s location (in
the preference space) relative to retailer 1.
Whereas t hese utilities apply to all consumers, not all
segments have access to all purchase options. Figure 1
details the choice set available to each segment. For
example, the channel-agnostic decided (AD) consumer
has access to all four options, whereas the store-only
undecided (SU) consumer only has the option of pur-
chasing from his preferred store (e.g., retailer 1). Thus,
consumer heterogeneity results in dierent choice sets
available to each segment.
Undecided consumers (both SU and AU), who do
not know which specific product they need, first visit
the retailer closer to their preference location (i.e., visit
retailer 1 if x <
1
2
and retailer 2, otherwise). After their
shopping trip, the store-only undecided (SU) segment
must decide whet her to buy the product that fits their
needs at the store or make no purchase; hence only
the corresponding u
s
-expression in (1) is relevant for
such a consumer. Channel-agnostic undecided (AU)
consumers can purchase in the store they first visit and
pay the store price, or return home and make an online
purchase from either retailer; the utility expressions
u
s
1
, u
on
1
, u
on
2
are thus relevant for AU consumers who
prefer retailer 1, and u
s
2
, u
on
1
, u
on
2
are relevant for AU
consumers who prefer retailer 2.
The Impact of Self-Matching Prices. We now examine
how self-matching practices by retailers impact con-
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 7
sumer utilities. Decided consumers know all prices for
the specific product they want, and if they shop at
the store oering self-matching, they can come armed
with the online price and request a price match. Thus,
decided consumers can obtain a price match in-store
whereas undecided consumers cannot.
When both retailers oer a self-matching pricing pol-
icy, i.e., under (SM
1
, SM
2
) (1, 1), a consumer at x 2
[0, 1] who can obtain a self-match faces the following
utilities:
u
on
1
v p
on
1
x, u
s
1
v min(p
s
1
, p
on
1
)x
u
on
2
v p
on
2
(1 x),
u
s
2
v min(p
s
2
, p
on
2
)(1 x).
(2)
Consumers who cannot obtain a price self-match
(i.e., undecided consumers) continue to face the cor-
responding utilities specified in Equation (1). Note
that although the utility expressions remain the same,
retailers may set dierent prices under dierent self-
matching scenarios. Hence, the equilibrium utilities
experienced by consumers will typically dier depend-
ing on retailer self-matching policies.
Next, consider consumers’ channel preferences.
Channel-agnostic decided (AD) consumers have no
particular preference for any channel and would
choose the lower-priced channel option. Store decided
(SD) consumers choose one of the stores based on their
preferences and prices. However, they can obtain the
lower online price if the retailer oers a self-matching
policy. Thus, the expressions for u
s
j
for j 1, 2 are dif-
ferent in (2) compared to (1). Undecided (AU and SU)
consumers do not know which product they want until
they visit the store. They face the same utilities under
(1, 1) as under (0, 0) since they cannot redeem match-
ing policies when they visit a retailer’s store without
making an additional costly set of trips, i.e., back home
to determine online prices and then back to a store to
make the purchase.
Utilities in the asymmetric subgame (1, 0), where
only retailer 1 oers to self-match prices, are defined
similar to the (0, 0) case, with only u
s
1
changing for
decided consumers, who can obtain a self-match only
from retailer 1 but not retailer 2:
6
u
s
1
v min(p
s
1
, p
on
1
)x.
4. Analysis
We begin our analysis by considering the benchmark
monopoly case, then the multichannel duopoly setting.
All proofs are in the appendix along with the defined
threshold values and constants. Note that in all cases,
we derive conditions for the market to be covered in
the proof; our text discussion will focus on the region
of coverage in equilibrium.
7
4.1. Benchmark Monopoly: A Single Entity Owns
Both Retailers
Consider a monopolist that jointly maximizes the prof-
its of two multichannel retailers at the endpoints of a
unit segment by choosing a self-matching policy and
setting prices.
8
The following holds:
Proposition 1. A monopolist cannot increase profits by
self-matching prices across channels.
The monopolist will price to extract the great-
est surplus from each channel. Because undecided
and decided consumers are present in both chan-
nels, the prices charged will be the same in both and
equal to the monopoly price of (v /2), regardless of
whether the monopolist oers a self-matching policy.
The monopolist thus obtains no additional profit when
oering the policy and will not oer it when it entails
a minimal implementation cost.
4.2. Multichannel Duopoly
We now consider the case of two competing multi-
channel retailers who make decisions according to the
timeline in Figure 1. We examine each of the possi-
ble self-matching policy subgames and conclude with
a result highlighting the conditions under which self-
matching emerges in equilibrium.
For notational convenience, we define the function
(p
k
1
, p
k
2
; ) :
1
2
+ (p
k
2
p
k
1
)/(2) to represent t he propor-
tion of demand obtained by retailer 1 from a specific
segment of consumers who face prices p
k
1
and p
k
2
from
the two retailers.
No Self-Matching—(0, 0). In the (0, 0) subgame wherein
neither retailer self-matches, store-only consumers (SD
and SU segments) purchase from the store channel
and pay the store price. Channel-agnostic (AD and
AU) consumers can also purchase from either retailer’s
online channel. AD consumers will begin their search
process online, whereas AU consumers will first visit
their preferred retailer to browse products, then return
home to purchase online after they discover the specific
product they wish to purchase. Retailers compete for
these two consumer segments in the online channel.
SU consumers visit the retailer closest in preference
to them to learn about products. Recall that these con-
sumers do not purchase online and do not switch stores
because of travel costs associated with multiple store
visits. Each retailer eectively has a subset (/2) of such
consumers.
On the other hand, SD consumers know the prod-
uct they want and are informed of all prices. They
purchase in-store, given their channel preference, but
make a decision on which store to visit after factoring
in their retailer preferences and prices. Thus, there is
intense competition among retailers for this segment,
since by reducing store price, a retailer can attract more
SD consumers.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
8 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
The profit functions of retailers 1 and 2 can be writ-
ten as
0, 0
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
| {z }
Channel-Agnostic Decided and Undecided
+ (1 )
(1 )(p
s
1
, p
s
2
)
| {z }
Store-Only Decided
+ /2
|{z}
Store-Only Undecided
p
s
1
,
0, 0
2
(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
(1 )(1 (p
s
1
, p
s
2
)) + /2
p
s
2
.
In the (0, 0) case, the online situation is similar
to retailers competing in a horizontally dierentiated
market comprised of only channel-agnostic consumers.
The resulting equilibrium prices, therefore, reflect the
strength of consumers’ preferences for retailers, with
ˆ
p
on
1
ˆ
p
on
2
. We refer to a price of as the “competi-
tive” price level to reflect the fact that this would be the
price charged in a standard Hotelling duopoly model
with one retail channel.
Next, we turn to the store channel, where we obtain
symmetric equilibrium prices of
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
8
>
>
>
><
>
>
>
>
:
v
2
,
v
1
2
+
1
1
,
1
,
v
>
1
2
+
1
1
. (3)
There are a few useful observations to be made here.
First, for v/
1
2
+ 1/(1 ), retailers serve the entire
market even though they charge the monopoly price
in-store. This is possible because of the existence of
SU consumers: Retailers prefer to charge the monopoly
price to extract all surplus from SU consumers if the
ratio of product value to retailer dierentiation is su-
ciently low. Second, if v/>
1
2
+ 1/(1 ), then retailers
charge a store price of /(1 ), which is larger than
the competitive price of . When v/ is suciently
large, retailers can no longer maintain monopoly prices
in-store and prefer to compete for SD consumers. How-
ever, the existence of SU consumers enables retailers
to charge more in-store than online, and the retailers
extract more surplus from both SU and SD segments.
Symmetric Self-Matching—(1, 1). In this case, both re-
tailers implement a self-matching policy. The first and
most obvious result of self-matching is the channel arbi-
trage eect, and the intuition here is straightforward.
Recall that SD consumers shop in-store and pay
ˆ
p
s
j
as
in Equation (3) absent a self-matching policy. However,
with a self-match they pay the lower online price while
shopping in-store, resulting in less profit for the retailer
due to arbitrage across channels.
Although this arbitrage intuition is correct, it is
incomplete in determining whether in equilibrium a
self-matching pricing policy will be adopted. When
a multichannel retailer chooses to self-match, there
emerges an important distinction between the store-
only decided (SD) and undecided (SU) consumers.
Whereas the SD consumers can obtain a price match,
SU consumers only know which product they desire
during a store visit. Because they lack evidence of a
lower online price, they always pay the store price.
Thus, even though the two segments of store con-
sumers obtain the product in-store, they eectively pay
dierent prices. Self-matching thus enables the retailer
to price discriminate consumers based on their deci-
sion stage.
Retailers profits in this self-matching setting are
thus
1, 1
1
(1 (1 ))
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
| {z }
Channel-Agnostic and Store-Only Decided
+ (1 )
2
p
s
1
| {z }
Store-Only Undecided
,
1, 1
2
(1 (1 ))(1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
2
p
s
2
.
In the pricing sub-game, retailers set equilibrium on-
line prices
ˆ
p
on
1
ˆ
p
on
2
, since there is no force to pre-
vent online prices from dropping to their competitive
level. However, retailers set store prices
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
(v
/2) to extract surplus from their respective “captive”
sets of SU customers, who pay the store price. We refer
to the ability to extract additional surplus from SU
consumers through self-matching as the decision-stage
discrimination eect.
Figure 2 illustrates pricing and purchase outcomes
across the (0, 0) and (1, 1) subgames. The dashed
regions cover the segments that pay the store price,
whereas the solid-filled regions show the segments
that pay the online price. In the (0, 0) subgame, SU
and SD consumers purchase in-store and pay the same
store price, whereas AU and AD consumers purchase
online and pay the online price. In the (1, 1) subgame,
SU and SD consumers purchase in-store, but SD con-
sumers now pay the online price. Thus, self-matching
allows a retailer to simultaneously price discriminate
consumers across decision stages in the store and de-
segment decided consumers across channels.
Asymmetric Self-Matching—(1, 0). Next, we explore
the case wherein retailer 1 oers a self-matching policy
while retailer 2 does not, i.e., the (1, 0) self-matching
subgame. By symmetry (or relabeling), similar results
follow in the (0, 1) subgame. Observe t hat SD con-
sumers who visit retailer 1’s store can purchase there
and pay the lower of the online and store price,
i.e., min(p
on
1
, p
s
1
). However, if an SD consumer visits
retailer 2’s store instead, she faces a price of p
s
2
and can-
not obtain the online price in-store (since retailer 2 does
not self-match). Moreover, by oering a self-matching
policy, and as long as its online price satisfies p
on
1
< p
s
2
,
retailer 1 attracts some SD consumers who are closer in
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 9
Figure 2. The Eects of Self-Matching
AU AD AD AU
SU SD SD SU
AU AD AD AU
SU SD SD SU
AU AD AD AU
SU SD SD SU
Retailer 1 Retailer 2
Online
In-store
Retailer 1 Retailer 2
Online
In-store
Retailer 1
Retailer 2
Online
In-store
(a) No self-matching—(0, 0)
(b) Symmetric self-matching—(1,1)
(c) Asymmetric self-matching—(1, 0)
Online price Store price
preference to the competing retailer 2 but who choose
to visit retailer 1s store in anticipation of paying the
lower online price through a self-match.
For SD consumers, under p
on
1
< p
s
1
, the store price
of retailer 1 is irrelevant (since they retrieve the price
match); the retailer can set a store price level to capture
the highest possible surplus from the SU consumers
who are closer to its location. Thus, decision-stage price
discrimination persists in the asymmetric subgame.
We obtain the following profit functions:
1, 0
1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
| {z }
Channel-Agnostic
+ (1 )
(1 )
1
(p
on
1
, p
s
2
)p
on
1
| {z }
Store-Only Decided
+ /2p
s
1
|{z}
Store-Only Undecided
,
1, 0
2
(1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
(1 )(1
1
(p
on
1
, p
s
2
)) + /2
p
s
2
.
Solving for the second-stage pricing subgame, we find
that the online price levels chosen by the retailers are
higher than the Hotelling competitive price of in both
channels and critically depend on the ratio of prod-
uct value v to the retailer dierentiation parameter
as follows. For v/ (
4
3
+ 1/(6(1 (1 ))) + /
(2(1 ))), both retailers will extract all surplus from
SU consumers and set prices
ˆ
p
on
1
+
(1 )(1 )(2v 3)
4(1 (1 ))
,
ˆ
p
on
2
+
(1 )(1 )(2v 3)
8(1 (1 )) 2
,
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
v
2
.
For v/>(4/3 + 1/(6(1 (1 ))) + /(2(1 ))),we
find that retailers set prices
ˆ
p
on
1
2
3
+
1
3(1 (1 ))
,
ˆ
p
on
2
5
6
+
1
6(1 (1 ))
,
ˆ
p
s
1
v
2
,
ˆ
p
s
2
ˆ
p
on
2
+
✓
2(1 )
.
Interestingly, equilibrium online prices in the asym-
metric self-matching (1, 0) case are greater than those
set in the no self-matching (0, 0) case and the sym-
metric self-matching (1, 1) case. The intuition follows
from the idea that although self-matching retailer 1
loses profit from the SD segment of consumers who
can invoke the price self-match, the policy eectively
acts like a “commitment device” to prevent online
prices from going all the way down to the compet-
itive level. More important, when only one retailer
self-matches online competition softens, which results
in channel-agnostic AD and AU consumers paying a
higher price (relative to the competitive online price of
they were paying under no self-matching or sym-
metric self-matching cases). Thus, self-matching has a
positive eect on profits through t his third mechanism,
which we term the online competition dampening eect.
Note that the situation in the asymmetric (1, 0) case
diers from the case when both retailers self-match.
Under (1 , 1), SD consumers can redeem the online
price at both retailers stores, which forces online
prices down to their competitive level . By con-
trast, Figure 2 illustrates how, in the asymmetric (1, 0)
case, SD consumers can only redeem the match from
retailer 1. Retailer 2 will price higher in-store relative
to retailer 1’s online price, as SD consumers and its
captive segment of SU consumers pay its store price,
whereas retailer 1 fully segments out its store con-
sumers through the self-matching policy invoked by
its SD consumers (while retailer 1’s SU consumers con-
tinue to pay its store price). However, to mitigate the
downside eect of channel arbitrage, retailer 1 does not
set its online price as low as ; this move also allows
it to extract greater surplus from the channel agnostic
segments. Because online prices are strategic comple-
ments across retailers, retailer 2’s best response is to
increase its online price as well. This results in online
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
10 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
Table 3. Eects of Self-Matching for Retailer 1 in a
Multichannel Duopoly
Relevant
Eect Subgames
() Channel Arbitrage: SD consumers redeem lower
online price in the store, reducing profits from SD.
(1, 0)(1 , 1)
(+) Decision-Stage Discrimination: Retailer avoids
competing for SD segment on store prices; instead
letting them obtain lower online prices. This
allows higher store prices to captive SU segment.
(1, 0)(1 , 1)
(+) Online Competition Dampening: Retailer charges
higher online price to mitigate arbitrage,
increasing profit from AD, AU, and SD segments.
(1, 0)
prices at both retailers being higher than the competi-
tive level, leading to online competition dampening.
The results detailed in this section are based on the
pricing subgame, taking the self-matching policies as
given. The pricing equilibria depend on the magni-
tudes of the three eects induced by self-matching.
Table 3 presents a summary of the eects we have iden-
tified. Note that the negative channel arbitrage eect
and the positive decision-stage discrimination eect
always occur for a self-matching retailer, while online
competition dampening occurs only when one self-
matches but the rival does not. We now examine the
full equilibrium results of the game beginning with the
self-matching strategy choices.
4.3. Self-Matching Policy Equilibria in a
Multichannel Duopoly
For a self-matching policy configuration to emerge in
equilibrium, it must be the case that neither retailer
would be better o by unilaterally deviating to oer a
dierent policy. Proposition 2 details the equilibrium
conditions and the resulting choices of self-matching
policies. Across all regions of the parameter space, we
restrict our focus to Pareto-dominant equilibria.
Proposition 2. In a duopoly featuring two multichannel
retailers, self-matching policies are determined by the follow-
ing mutually exclusive regions
Asymmetric equilibrium (1, 0). One retailer will oer
to self-match its prices while the other will not when product
values are relatively low or retailer dierentiation is high.
Symmetric non-matching equilibrium (0, 0). Neither
retailer will self-match its prices when product values and
retailer dierentiation are at intermediate levels.
Symmetric matching equilibrium (1, 1). Both retailers
will self-match prices when product values are high or re-
tailer dierentiation is low.
The above result indicates that all three types of
joint strategies can emerge in equilibrium depending
on the nature of the product and degree of compet-
itive interaction. To understand the intuition behind
the emergence of the dierent equilibria, it is critical to
examine how the focal retailer’s best response function
evolves as the ratio of product value to retailer dif-
ferentiation (v/) changes. We translate best response
functions into equilibria in Figure 3. The top arrow
depicts retailer 1’s best response if retailer 2 does not
self-match. The middle arrow depicts retailer 1’s best
response if retailer 2 self-matches. The dominant eects
for retailer 1 are listed below the arrows. The bottom
arrow shows the emergent Pareto-dominant equilibria.
The best response of the focal retailer depends on the
competitor’s self-matching strategy as well as the three
eects we have previously described, i.e., channel arbi-
trage, decision-stage discrimination, and online competition
dampening.
Retailer 1’s Best Response to Retailer 2 Not Self-
Matching. For low v/, the retailer’s store price (v
/2) is relatively close to its competitive online price
because there is little additional surplus the retailer
can extract from its captive SU consumers by pricing
higher in-store. As a result, eects that have an impact
on the store channel, i.e., the negative channel arbi-
trage eect and the positive decision-stage discrimina-
tion eect are negligible. However, online prices can
increase with self-matching due to the online compe-
tition dampening eect. This leads retailer 1 to oer
a self-matching policy to take advantage of the addi-
tional profits from the online channel.
As v/ increases, so does the dierence in prices
across channels. For intermediate values of v/, the
retailer can extract more surplus from SU consumers,
driving it to price higher in-store even if it does not self-
match, thus reducing the benefits of decision-stage dis-
crimination. Because a self-matching policy allows SD
consumers to redeem the lower online price, the chan-
nel arbitrage eect increases. As competition in the
online channel is more intense than in the store chan-
nel, the positive online competition dampening eect
can no longer overcome t he negative channel arbitrage
eect. Consequently, the channel arbitrage eect dom-
inates the other two eects, and t he retailer no longer
finds it profitable to self-match as a best response.
At high v/ levels, retailer 1 is compelled to compete
more intensely for SD consumers closer to retailer 2 in
preference, resulting in a store price of /(1 ) that
no longer grows in v, if the retailer does not self-match.
Thus, the negative impact due to channel arbitrage is
limited. However, if the retailer were to oer a self-
matching policy, decision-stage discrimination would
allow it to charge the monopoly price (v /2) to cap-
tive SU consumers, which increases as v/ increases.
This creates a strong positive impact on profits, result-
ing in retailer 1 choosing to oer self-matching.
Retailer 1’s Best Response to Retailer 2 Self-Matching.
We now turn to the case wherein retailer 2 decides to
oer a self-matching policy.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 11
Figure 3. (Color online) Retailer Best Responses
Best response of
retailer 1 given
retailer 2 does
not self-match
Self-match Do not self-match
Do not self-match Self-match
Equilibrium regions
(1,1)(0,1) or (1, 0) (0, 0)
Dominant effect
Dominant effect
Online competition
dampening (+)
Channel arbitrage (–) Decision stage
discrimination (+)
Online competition
dampening (+)
Decision stage
discrimination (+)
Best response of
retailer 1 given
retailer 2 self-
matches
Self-match
v
à
v
à
v
à
Recall that when both retailers self-match, the online
competition dampening eect ceases to exist. Because
retailer 2 is self-matching, its actions will result in
online competition dampening only if retailer 1 does
not self-match. This creates an incentive for retailer 1
to refrain from self-matching at low values of v/ ,to
benefit from online competition dampening through
strategic complementarity in prices. Furthermore, at
low values of v/, the decision-stage discrimination
eect is small as retailer 1 cannot extract a substantial
amount of surplus from SU consumers.
As v/ increases, the benefit of decision-stage dis-
crimination grows because the retailer can extract
greater surplus from SU consumers if it can charge
them a dierent price than SD consumers. This leads
retailer 1 to adopt self-matching for high values of v/.
Strategic Substitutes or Complements. We integrate
the best responses to obtain equilibrium strategies and
focus on whether self-matching strategies across retail-
ers are strategic complements or substitutes. We find
from the best responses that at low product values,
and/or at high levels of retailer dierentiation, the self-
matching strategies act like strategic substitutes, so t hat
a retailer will choose the strategy opposite to that of its
competitor. As v/ increases to an intermediate level,
we obtain a symmetric equilibrium where no retailer
self-matches and strategies are strategic complements.
Finally, when v/ is above a high threshold, the strong
impact of decision-stage discrimination leads to self-
matching being a dominant strategy regardless of what
the competitor chooses. Figure 4 shows the equilibrium
regions that emerge in the v/ $ space for a fixed
value of 2(0, 1) based on Proposition 2.
Next, we turn to how the equilibrium regions are
aected by and .
Corollary 1. An increase in the fraction of undecided con-
sumers will grow the asymmetric equilibrium region and
shrink the symmetric equilibrium regions.
According to the corollary, retailer 1 has more of an
incentive to oer a self-matching policy as increases,
implying that the v/-region for which we can sustain
the (1, 0) equilibrium expands. To understand the intu-
ition for Corollary 1, consider the case of focal retailer
1’s best response when retailer 2 does not self-match.
As the fraction of undecided consumers increases, the
Figure 4. Equilibrium Regions
Symmetric (0, 0)
Asymmetric (1, 0)
v/à
(ratio of product
value to
differentiation)
Ç (size of undecided segment)
Symmetric (1,1)
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
12 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
retailers stand to gain more from online competition
dampening (because of the greater fraction of AU con-
sumers). Thus, if retailer 1 self-matches, retailer 2 will
refrain from doing so (because when both self-match,
the online competition dampening eect is nullified).
The next corollary examines the eect of on the
equilibrium regions.
Corollary 2. An increase in the fraction of channel-agnostic
consumers will grow the region where retailers choose not
to self-match.
The profitability of self-matching largely depends on
the existence of SU consumers. When the fraction of
store-only consumers decreases (i.e., grows), retail-
ers can no longer benefit as much from decision-stage
discrimination. Thus, the profitability of oering a self-
matching policy decreases as increases.
4.4. Profitability of Self-Matching
We have thus far analyzed how retailers decide
whether to adopt self-matching policies and character-
ized the strategies that can be sustained in equilibrium.
Here, we examine the profit impact of having self-
matching available as a strategic option. The key issue
we seek to understand is whether retailers are com-
pelled by competitive forces to adopt self-matching,
even though it might not be beneficial and could result
in lower equilibrium profits were self-matching not an
option. The result in Proposition 3 addresses this issue.
Proposition 3. The profit implications of self-matching,
compared to the baseline case where self-matching is not
available as an option, are as follows
(a) In the asymmetric equilibrium (1, 0). The retailer
oering to self-match earns greater profits, but the competing
retailer earns lower profits.
(b) In the symmetric self-matching equilibrium (1, 1).
Both retailers earn higher profits when product valuation is
high or retailer dierentiation is low. Otherwise, they both
earn lower profits.
We find that at low values of v/, the profit impact
of self-matching is asymmetric, with the self-matching
retailer obtaining higher profits.
We find t hat in the region of v/ where symmet-
ric self-matching occurs in equilibrium, when v/ is
close to its lower bound, self-matching reduces profits
for both retailers because of the lower positive impact
of decision-stage discrimination and the increasing
negative impact of channel arbitrage. This interaction
results in a situation wherein both retailers would have
benefitted had self-matching not been an option. How-
ever, when v/ is high, both retailers choose to self-
match and ear n higher profits. This occurs because at
high v/, decision-stage discrimination overtakes the
negative impact of channel arbitrage. Overall, we find
that the availability of self-matching as a strategy may
enhance profits for at least one retailer and can also do
so for both retailers for a range of parameters, high-
lighting the importance of self-matching as a strategic
option.
5. Extensions
The base model analyzed in Section 4 focused on devel-
oping an understanding of the mechanisms underlying
the eectiveness of self-matching and the conditions
for retailers to implement the policy in equilibrium.
Here, we have two main objectives. First, we will exam-
ine additional settings that are relevant to retailers as
they contemplate whet her to oer a self-matching pric-
ing policy. Second, we relax a few key assumptions in
the baseline model, with a view towards increasing the
range of applicability of the findings. Proofs for results
presented in this section are provided in Appendix B
and the Electronic Supplement.
5.1. Impact of “Smart-Device Enabled Consumers
The baseline model characterized undecided con-
sumers as not knowing what specific product they
want until they visit a store to evaluate which item
from the many available options best fits their needs.
They could not invoke a self-matching policy because
they were in-store at the time of their final decision,
and there was no way for them to access the Internet to
produce evidence of a lower online price.
Here, we recognize the increasing importance of
mobile devices to alter this dynamic and examine the
implications for self-matching policies. Retail Touch-
Points (Fiorletta 2013) notes that, Amplified price
transparency—due to the instant availability of infor-
mation via the web and mobile devices—has encour-
aged retailers to rethink their omnichannel pricing
strategies. Intuitively, one might expect that the
greater the proportion of consumers who carry smart
devices and take the trouble to check online when
in-store, the less profitable self-matching should be
(because of the increased threat of cross-channel arbi-
trage). We show t hat this need not be the case.
Suppose that a fraction µ (0 <µ<1) of consumers
has access to the Internet while shopping in-store.
We refer to these consumers as “smart” to reflect the
notion that with the aid of Internet-enabled smart-
phone devices these consumers can easily obtain
online price information while in-store. Store-only
undecided smart consumers can now invoke a self-
matching policy if the online price oered by a retailer
is lower than its store price. Channel-agnostic unde-
cided smart consumers will eectively behave as we
have already modeled in the baseline model.
An increase in smart consumers can be understood
as increasing the fraction of store-only undecided (SU)
consumers who redeem the online price. However,
these consumers can only purchase from the retailer
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 13
they first visit, by contrast to store-only decided (SD)
consumers who have the option of buying from other
retailers at the outset. To see how the existence of smart
consumers impacts retailers’ strategies, consider the
profits retailers earn if they both oer to self-match
1, 1
1
(1 (1 ))
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )
2
((1 µ)p
s
1
+ µp
on
1
),
1, 1
2
(1 (1 ))(1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
2
((1 µ)p
s
2
+ µp
on
2
).
Solving for the equilibrium reveals that retailers will
set p
on
1
p
on
2
(1 µ) + µ/(1 (1 )) and
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
v /2. Note that the online prices are increasing
in µ. We detail how smart consumers impact retailers’
equilibrium incentives to self-match in Proposition 4.
Proposition 4. In a duopoly with two multichannel retail-
ers, where some consumers can use a smart device in-store
to obtain online price information
(a) As the fraction of smart consumers increases, the
asymmetric equilibrium region grows, whereas the symmet-
ric self-matching equilibrium region shrinks.
(b) Retailer profits can increase in the fraction of smart
consumers.
At low product values, holding fixed the other
model parameters, more smart consumers enhance the
online competition dampening eect in the asymmet-
ric equilibrium, which allows retailers to price higher
online when oering to self-match. On the other hand,
the conditions for symmetric self-matching policies to
emerge in equilibrium for high product values become
more stringent as µ grows. That is, as µ ! 1, the sym-
metric self-matching region for high v shrinks in size to
zero. This happens because the existence of smart con-
sumers greatly erodes the positive decision-stage dis-
crimination eect of self-matching, as there are fewer
SU consumers who will still pay the high store price,
while more consumers pay the lower online price,
thereby reducing retailers’ incentives to self-match.
Thus, and somewhat counterintuitively, the presence
of smart consumers need not decrease the profitability
of a self-matching retailer (see proof of Proposition 4
in Appendix B for details of the profit enhancing case).
On the contrary, smart consumers can enable retail-
ers to charge higher online prices, increasing the prof-
itability of self-matching policies. This suggests that
given current technology trends, horizontally dieren-
tiated retailers would find it worthwhile to more care-
fully examine whether self-matching is an appropriate
strategic option.
5.2. Mixed Duopoly: Multichannel
Retailer and E-Tailer
We consider the case of a multichannel retailer facing
a pure online e-tailer, i.e., a “mixed duopoly market.
This market structure is becoming more important for
a number of multichannel retailers, e.g., several retail-
ers find that Amazon and potentially other e-tailers are
their primary rivals. Past research has considered the
strategic implications of direct sellers, such as e-tailers,
competing with traditional retail channels (Balasubra-
manian 1998). Motivation for mixed channel structures
and a dierent type of consumer heterogeneity across
channels has been studied by Yoo and Lee (2011). How-
ever, to our knowledge, decision-stage heterogeneity
and self-matching policies have not been examined in
this setting.
We denote the focal multichannel retailer as retailer 1
and the online-only e-tailer as retailer 2. In this setting,
only retailer 1 can oer a self-matching policy in stage 1
of the game. Subsequently, both retailers set prices and
compete for demand per the timeline in Figure 1.
First, consider the case wherein the multichannel
retailer does not self-match its prices. Store-only con-
sumers can only consider retailer 1’s store channel and
are captive to this retailer, whereas channel-agnostic
consumers have the option of shopping across the two
retailers’ online sites. Profits for both retailers can be
expressed as follows:
0, 0
1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
| {z }
Channel-Agnostic Decided and Undecided
+ (1 )p
s
1
| {z }
Store-Only Decided and Undecided
, (4)
0, 0
2
(1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
| {z }
Channel-Agnostic Decided and Undecided
.
Retailer 1 serves as an eective monopolist for store-
only consumers (SD and SU segments), who comprise
a combined segment of size 1 , and will attempt to
extract surplus from them by setting a store price of
ˆ
p
s
1
v . Note that by contrast to the multichannel
duopoly, store-only decided consumers do not drive
down prices in the mixed duopoly case because the e-
tailer does not have a store that serves as a competitive
option. Both retailers compete online for the channel-
agnostic consumers, who form a segment of size .
We allow for channel-agnostic undecided consumers
who are closer in preference to retailer 2, the e-tailer,
to browse the product category at retailer 1’s store and
then purchase online from the e-tailer. The equilibrium
online prices are at the competitive level, with
ˆ
p
on
1
ˆ
p
on
2
.
Next, consider the (1, 0) subgame where the multi-
channel retailer oers a self-matching policy. SD con-
sumers can now retrieve the multichannel retailer’s
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
14 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
online price in-store. Consider the retailers’ profits as
given below
1, 0
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
| {z }
Channel-Agnostic Decided and Undecided
+ (1 )(1 )p
on
1
| {z }
Store-Only Decided
+ (1 )p
s
1
| {z }
Store-Only Undecided
, (5)
1, 0
2
(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
.
As in the no self-matching case, online competition
places downward pressure on the price levels p
on
1
and
p
on
2
in the (1, 0) case. However, a portion of store con-
sumers, i.e., the (1 )(1 )-sized SD segment, now
receive the online price by invoking the self-match pol-
icy instead of paying the store price. As in the mul-
tichannel duopoly case, retailer 1 thus faces a channel
arbitrage eect when it allows consumers to obtain a
price match. We might intuitively expect self-matching
to be unprofitable, especially since the SD consumers,
regardless of retailer preferences, cannot defect to the
e-tailer due to their preference for the store channel.
However, once again, the online competition dampening
eect can act to increase profitability when the multi-
channel retailer chooses to self-match. The following
proposition reflects the net impact of these eects.
Proposition 5. In a mixed duopoly featuring a multichan-
nel retailer and a pure e-tailer, the multichannel retailer
adopts a self-matching policy when product value is rela-
tively low or retailer dierentiation is high. Otherwise, the
retailer will not adopt a self-matching policy.
The intuition for Proposition 5 follows naturally
from the implications of the online competition damp-
ening eect in the asymmetric case of the multichan-
nel duopoly scenario. When retailer 1 decides to self-
match, there is a cross-channel arbitrage externality. In
a bid to reduce the negative impact of channel arbi-
trage, the multichannel retailer who implements a self-
match has an incentive to raise its online price relative
to the no self-matching case. Strategic complementar-
ity in prices leads both retailers to set higher online
prices than under no self-matching. Note that there is
no decision-stage discrimination eect. SU consumers
pay the same price regardless of whether there is self-
matching because the e-tailer has no rival store to
induce competition for t he SD segment and lower the
multichannel retailer’s store price.
The trade-o between the channel arbitrage and
competition dampening eects depends on v/. For
low enough v (or high ), the self-matching multi-
channel retailer prices similarly across channels; thus
channel arbitrage is low. In this case, the online compe-
tition dampening eect dominates and grows in v/.
However, the negative channel arbitrage eect also
increases in v/ (as SD consumers redeem the lower
online price) and eventually dominates the online com-
petition dampening eect. As a result, self-matching
emerges as an equilibrium outcome only for low values
of v/.
Turning to the profit impact of self-matching on the
e-tailer, we find the following:
Corollary 3. In a mixed duopoly, the e-tailer makes higher
profits when the multichannel retailer uses a self-matching
policy.
Thus, a self-matching policy has a positive external-
ity on the e-tailer due to reduced competition in the
online channel, which allows the e-tailer to increase
prices. This holds even t hough the e-tailer’s price level
is lower than that of the multichannel retailer; t he latter
internalizes a higher benefit of raising its online price
because of the positive impact on its store channel.
5.3. Additional Analyses
5.3.1. Markets with a Possibility of Expanding De-
mand. To relax t he assumption that all markets are
fully covered, we focus on a scenario where retailers
compete in a linear city and also face markets that are
not fully covered but can expand as retailers reduce
prices.
9
Specifically, retailers are at x 0 and x 1
on a Hotelling line of length
1
5
(3 + 6v/) such that
the distance between retailers is still equal to 1 but
they face additional monopoly (captive) consumer seg-
ments outside of the unit interval (x < 0 and x > 1).
We conduct equilibrium analysis for high levels of
v/ and find that both retailers will choose to oer self-
matching policies. This result coincides with Proposi-
tion 2, where we found that symmetric self-matching
emerges in equilibrium at high levels of v/. How-
ever, by contrast to the profitability results in Proposi-
tion 3, retailers earn lower profits when self-matching
than in the case where self-matching is not available
as a strategic option. This is because retailers now
have an incentive to keep store prices low, even when
self-matching, to attract consumers outside of the unit
interval. As a result, the decision-stage discrimination
eect is reduced, and the profitability of self-matching
suers. The following proposition summarizes our
finding:
Proposition 6. In a market with demand that can expand
characterized by the existence of consumer segments beyond
the Hotelling unit interval on both sides, both retailers oer
self-matching policies if the product value is high or the
level of dierentiation is low. However, both retailers earn
lower profits than had self-matching not existed as a strategic
option.
5.3.2. Retailer Processing Costs. Retailers may incur
a processing cost when dealing with consumers who
redeem a self-matching policy, for example, the sta
time for verifying the evidence and entering it into the
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 15
system. The idea here is somewhat analogous to that of
hassle costs developed in Desai and Purohit (2004). In
fully covered markets, an increase in retailer process-
ing costs will reduce the profitability of self-matching
by, in eect, increasing the magnitude of the channel
arbitrage eect. As a result, self-matching is more dif-
ficult to sustain in equilibrium and the region labeled
(1, 1) in Figure 4 shrinks as retailer processing costs
grow. In the Electronic Supplement, we illustrate the
impact a small but non-zero retailer cost of servicing
consumers who redeem a self-matching policy has on
retailer prices and profits to highlight the greater chan-
nel arbitrage eect and the reduced profitability of self-
matching.
5.3.3. Dierent Structure of Consumer Heterogeneity
in a Monopoly Setting. Proposition 1 establishes that
self-matching will never be adopted by a monopolist
and provides a benchmark for the duopoly analysis.
However, the monopolist may choose to self-match
in models that allow for a dierent structure of con-
sumer heterogeneity. To illustrate how self-matching
may be profitable for a monopolist, in the Electronic
Supplement we develop an alternative model where
consumers exhibit heterogeneity in their travel costs
and product valuations. All consumers are at first
undecided and must visit the retailer’s store to iden-
tify their preferred product. Consumers have heteroge-
neous product valuations that are perfectly correlated
with their travel costs, i.e., consumers with a high prod-
uct valuation have a high travel cost, and consumers
with a low product valuation have a low travel cost.
A self-matching policy may enable the monopolist to
price discriminate by charging a higher store price and
selling to store-only consumers with a high travel cost
and a high product valuation as these consumers may
find it costly to visit the store multiple times to redeem
a self-matching policy.
5.4. Consumer Survey
We conducted a consumer survey to characterize
market conditions across a range of retail product
categories. Our primar y goal is to evaluate whether
consumers exhibit heterogeneity along the dimensions
incorporated in the model, o-line versus online chan-
nel preference, horizontal preference across retailers
within a category, and decision-stage heterogeneity
(decided versus undecided). We also want to examine
observed market outcomes, in terms of firm behavior,
to assess the degree to which our model analysis cor-
responds to these outcomes. Full details on the survey
and its results are provided in Appendix C, and survey
questions are detailed in the Electronic Supplement.
Broadly, the survey findings point to substantial con-
sumer heterogeneity and lend support to our model
tenets.
Connection to Market Outcomes. We discuss how
the insights from our theoretical model, when com-
bined with the survey findings, compared with the
observed self-matching policies of firms across a range
of product categories (from pet supplies to electron-
ics). Obser ved Policies are detailed in Appendix D. We
emphasize that to empirically establish a causal con-
nection between our hypothesized forces and observed
market outcomes, a more thorough empirical investi-
gation is required. The survey results are intended to
provide us with preliminary evidence that may encour-
age such subsequent research.
Here, we focus on Figure 5 and t he model pre-
dictions per Proposition 2. Figure 5 shows a scatter
of product categories and indicates the self-matching
outcomes of major players above each category label
observed in the market. The ratio of value to dier-
entiation is indicated on the vertical axis and the pro-
portion of undecided consumers is indicated on the
horizontal axis, as measured by the survey.
First, we observe that the pet supply market, which
was found to have few undecided consumers and low
relative product value, reflects an asymmetric (1, 0)
outcome in practice, consistent with what the model
predicts. Second, the apparel and low-end depart-
ment stores markets, characterized by intermediate rel-
ative value and medium to high levels of undecided
consumers, demonstrate a no-self-matching, or (0, 0)
outcome in practice, again consistent with model pre-
dictions. Finally, we examine the markets with all firms
self-matching in practice (1, 1), i.e., electronics, upscale
department stores, home improvement, and oce sup-
plies. We find (with the exception of oce supply
Figure 5. (Color online) Market Characteristics and
Outcomes
10 20 30 40 50 60
0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
Market characteristics
Proportion of undecided
Value/Differentiation
Pet supply
Electronics
Home improvement
Apparel
Upscale department
Low department
Office supply
(1, 0)
(1,1)
(1,1)
(0,0)
(1,1)
(0, 0)
(1,1)
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
16 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
products) that they have a high relative value and
an intermediate proportion of undecided consumers,
which is consistent with our analysis. As for oce sup-
ply firms, they may view their primary competition
as coming from pure e-tailers such as Amazon rather
than from multichannel rivals.
10
Whereas t his oers suggestive and initial evidence
of the connection between market characteristics and
self-matching strategic choices in accordance with our
model predictions, we expect further careful exami-
nation across other product categories to be valuable.
An empirical investigation of this phenomenon would
also be useful and complementary to our theoretical
analysis.
6. Discussion, Limitations, and
Conclusion
The self-matching pricing policy has become an impor-
tant strategic aspect of multichannel retailing and is
used in a variety of markets, including consumer elec-
tronics, discount retail, and home improvement. Our
paper is, to our knowledge, the first attempt to model
this strategic pricing policy and investigate how a com-
pany’s self-matching decision is determined by con-
sumer behavior and the competitive landscape.
Retailers in our model choose whether to oer a self-
matching pricing policy in the first stage and then set
price levels in the second stage. The retailers’ products
are horizontally dierentiated, with consumers having
heterogeneous preferences over retailers. We further
allow for consumer heterogeneity along two additional
dimensions, decision stage and channel preference.
Thus, we explicitly capture a wide variety of DMPs for
consumers enabled by the multichannel setting.
The analysis illustrates how retailers in a multichan-
nel setting face downward price pressure in-store from
competition induced by the presence of store-only
decided consumers. By self-matching, a retailer relin-
quishes its ability to charge dierent prices to decided
consumers across channels (desegmentation). Channel
desegmentation induces channel arbitrage, but pro-
duces another eect: It can act as a commitment device
to increase online prices when only one retailer chooses
to self-match. We refer to this as the online competi-
tion dampening eect. Self-matching may also enable
the retailer to charge store-only undecided consumers
a higher store price, which we call the decision-stage
discrimination eect; this can result in both retailers
self-matching.
Self-matching is thus profitable when the posi-
tive eects of online competition dampening and/or
decision-stage discrimination overcome the negative
eects of channel arbitrage. We further find that the
profitability of self-matching is determined by prod-
uct value (relative to retailer dierentiation), as well as
consumer heterogeneity across dierent dimensions,
such as decision stage and channel preference.
Beyond the baseline model, we consider several ex-
tensions, one of which explicitly models a setting with
smart-device enabled (“smart”) consumers, who can
look up online prices while in-store, an increasingly
prevalent phenomenon. We find that self-matching can
increase retailer profitability as the proportion of smart
consumers increases. This consumer trend may prove
to be an important issue for retailers to consider when
making pricing policy decisions going forward.
Our model yields results that are empirically
testable. First, retailers oering to self-match will have
a larger online to store price discrepancy relative to
those that do not self-match. Second, we should find
asymmetric self-matching equilibrium configurations
in markets with relatively low-valued products (or
highly dierentiated retailers). Third, as the penetra-
tion of smart devices among consumers increases,
online prices set by retailers oering to self-match are
expected to rise. A consumer survey we conducted pro-
vides suggestive evidence of face validity as to how
the equilibrium predictions of the model broadly cor-
respond to the emergent self-matching configurations
in practice across a number of industries.
Although we believe this to be the first research to
rigorously examine t he idea of self-matching as a pric-
ing strategy, the present paper has several limitations
that could be addressed in future research. First, we
do not model competitive price-matching policies. Such
policies have been extensively studied in the literature,
and our focus is retailers with dierentiated product
assortments, where competitive price-matching does
not play a role. It would be interesting to exam-
ine whether self-matching complements or substitutes
competitive matching policies in settings where rival
retailers sell identical products. Second, by assuming
suciently large consumer travel costs for store vis-
its beyond the initial visit, we ensure that retailers can
price-discriminate their captive consumers who find it
too costly to search additional stores for product infor-
mation. We incorporated a variety of consumer DMPs
and preference dimensions. However, it would be use-
ful to consider a richer model of consumer search, for
example, where consumers could visit a retailer’s store
and then decide whether to visit a second based on
expectations of price as well as the benefits they may
obtain. Such an eort would connect with the search
literature, and it would be useful to examine whether
self-matching then leads to more search and larger
consideration sets in the spirit of Diamond (1971) and
Liu and Dukes (2013). Third, the dimensions of con-
sumer heterogeneity might be correlated, e.g., con-
sumers who prefer store shopping may also be more
undecided. While we do not expect this to change our
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 17
primary findings, careful modeling of these dependen-
cies might reveal additional eects. Fourth, it would
be interesting to investigate how new types of compe-
tition could feature self-matching, e.g., such as Ama-
zon competing with other sellers on its platform (Jiang
et al. 2011). Finally, although we expect the mecha-
nisms detailed here to apply to the case wherein there
are ex ante dierences among retailers (based on costs
or customer loyalty) beyond horizontal dierentiation,
there may be additional insights obtained in modeling
the more general case.
Broadly, our findings suggest that although a self-
matching policy may initially appear to be an unprof-
itable but necessary evil, it has more subtle and pos-
itive competitive implications. Indeed, self-matching
can be profitably used as a strategic lever and can
result in higher profits for all retailers in the industry.
Multichannel retailers should therefore treat their self-
matching decisions as an important element of their
overall cross-channel strategy, taking into account the
products they sell, consumer characteristics, as well as
the competitive landscape.
Acknowledgments
The authors thank participants at the 2012 Marketing Science
conference for comments and helpful feedback. All errors are
the authors’.
Appendix A. Proofs of Propositions
Proof of Proposition 1
First, we determine interior and corner solutions without
self-matching. At price p, consumer demand is D(p)
min(2(v p)/,1). For an interior optimal price, we have the
first-order condition (FOC) 0 p/ + (v p)/ )
ˆ
p v/2.
The condition for an interior solution is v <. When we have
a corner solution, i.e., under v >, the monopolist sets a price
of
ˆ
p v /2. In the rest of the proof, we focus on the case
wherein the markets are covered, i.e., v >.
The monopolist’s profit is determined as follows:
SM0
1
(1 )(p
on
1
+ (1 )p
s
1
) + (p
on
1
+ (1 )p
s
1
),
SM1
1
(1 )(p
on
1
+ (1 ) min(p
on
1
, p
s
1
))
+ (p
on
1
+ (1 )p
s
1
),
so the demand from all segments is equal to 1.
11
To solve for prices, the consumer farthest from t he monop-
olist must be indierent between purchasing or not. This
yields v p
s
1
/2 0 and v p
on
1
/2 0 in the case
of no self-matching policy. Prices are then
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
on
1
v
/2. Similarly, for when the retailer self-matches, we solve
v p
s
1
/2 0, v min(p
on
1
, p
s
1
)/2 0, and v p
on
1
/2 0. Regardless of whether SD consumers choose to
redeem the self-matching policy, the multichannel retailer
will set identical prices across channels, equal to those set had
it not self-matched:
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
on
1
v /2. As the profits under the
two conditions are equal, the monopolist will always prefer
SM 0, which weakly dominates SM 1.
Below, we refer to m as the cost of undertaking a second shopping
trip for store-only undecided consumers. We derive bounds on m
that ensure the consumer behavior specified in our assumptions.
Proof of Proposition 2
First, we separately consider each subgame. Then, we com-
pare the profits from each subgame to derive the bounds for
the equilibrium results. The following constraints must be
imposed:
v > 3/2 ensures that all markets are fully covered,
<5/8 ensures that no retailer sets such a high online
price to earn zero demand from decided consumers in the
(1, 0) subgame;
v <(1/ + 1/(4(1 )) /(36(1 (1 ))
2
)+ (7 11)/
(36(1 (1 ))) + 7/18) ensures that no retailer wants to
exclusively price for its captive segment of store-only unde-
cided consumers and forgo all demand for store-only decided
consumers;
m > v 3/2 ensures that no store-only undecided con-
sumers switch stores after their first visit, and that no con-
sumer returns home and visits the store a second time to
redeem a self-matching policy.
We focus on the case wherein >0, so that there are at
least some undecided consumers.
No Matching—(0, 0). Channel-agnostic consumers will pur-
chase online. Store-only consumers will buy in-store. All con-
sumers will pay the price set in the channel from which they
buy. The retailers will earn profits
0, 0
1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )
(1 )
1
(p
s
1
, p
s
2
) +
2
p
s
1
,
0, 0
2
(1
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
(1 )(1
1
(p
s
1
, p
s
2
)) +
2
p
s
2
.
We solve for the FOCs @
0, 0
j
/@p
s
j
0 and @
0, 0
j
/@p
on
j
0 for
j 2{1, 2}, and check for corner solutions. We find an interior
solution with equilibrium prices at
ˆ
p
on
1
ˆ
p
on
2
and
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
/(1 ) for v/ >
1
2
+ 1/(1 ), and a corner solution
in store prices with
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
v /2 for v/
1
2
+ 1/(1 ).
The store price is higher than the online price in all cases
as retailers have an incentive to price higher for their cap-
tive segment of store-only consumers. The binding condition
for an interior solution requires that all SU consumers pur-
chase in equilibrium. For retailer 1, this can be written as
v p
s
1
/2 > 0 (the utility for the SU consumer farthest away
from store 1 is greater than zero). When this condition fails
(i.e., v/
1
2
+ 1/(1 )), we have a corner solution where
retailers set local monopoly prices v /2 in-store. No other
constraints apply and there are no other corner solutions. The
equilibrium profits earned by retailers are
0, 0
1
0, 0
2
8
>
>
>
><
>
>
>
>
:
1
4
[2v(1 )(1 3)],
v
1
2
+
1
1
,
2
1 +
(1 )
1
,
v
>
1
2
+
1
1
.
Symmetric Self-Matching—(1, 1). Channel-agnostic con-
sumers will purchase online and pay the online price.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
18 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
Store-only decided consumers will buy in-store, but will
redeem the online price of the store they purchase from.
Store-only undecided consumers will buy in the store they
first visit and will pay the store price. The retailers will earn
profits
1, 1
1
(1 (1 ))(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )
2
p
s
1
,
1, 1
2
(1 (1 ))(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
2
p
s
2
,
and set prices
ˆ
p
on
1
ˆ
p
on
2
online and
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
v /2
in-store. The online price is the familiar competitive price
and is an interior solution to the FOCs @
1, 1
j
/@p
on
j
0 for
j 2{1, 2}. Dierentiating with respect to store prices yields
@
1, 1
j
/@p
s
j
(1 )(/2) > 0, implying a corner solution. The
retailers will set the highest store price they can, ensuring
that all SU consumers purchase, which is v /2. There are
no other corner solutions. The equilibrium profits earned by
retailers are
1, 1
1
1, 1
2
1
2
(1 (1 )) + (1 )
v
2
◆
.
Asymmetric Self-Matching—(1, 0). Channel-agnostic con-
sumers will purchase online and pay the online price. Store-
only decided consumers will buy in-store, but will redeem
the online price (as it will be lower) if they buy from the
self-matching retailer. They will pay the store price if they
buy from the non-self-matching retailer. Store-only unde-
cided consumers will buy from the store they first visit and
pay the store price. The retailers profits are then
1, 0
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )
(1 )(p
on
1
, p
s
2
)p
on
1
+
2
p
s
1
,
1, 0
2
(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
(1 )(1 (p
on
1
, p
s
2
)) +
2
p
s
2
.
The FOCs can be written as
@
1, 0
2
@p
s
2
0 ,
@
1, 0
j
@p
on
j
0 for j 2{1, 2},
and
@
1, 0
1
@p
s
1
(1 )
2
> 0.
In equilibrium, there is an interior solution for online
prices and for the store price of retailer 2 and a corner solu-
tion for the store price of retailer 1, for large v. The retailers
set online prices
ˆ
p
on
1
(
2
3
+ 1/(3(1 (1 )))) and
ˆ
p
on
2
(
5
6
+ 1/(6(1 (1 )))) and store prices
ˆ
p
s
1
v /2 and
ˆ
p
s
2
ˆ
p
on
2
+ ✓/(2(1 )) for v/>
4
3
+ 1/(6(1 (1 ))) +
/(2(1 )).
Otherwise, if v is small, we have a corner solution for
p
s
2
which yields prices
ˆ
p
on
1
+ ((1 )(1 )(2v 3))/
(4(1 (1 )) ),
ˆ
p
on
2
+ ((1 )(1 )(2v 3))/
(8(1 (1 )) 2) online and
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
v /2 in-store.
The binding threshold on v for an interior solution requires
that all of retailer 2’s SU consumers purchase in equilib-
rium. In other words, v p
s
2
/2 > 0. Substituting the inte-
rior solution equilibrium store price for retailer 2 into the
inequality shows that the corner solution holds for v/
4
3
+
1/(6(1 (1 ))) + /(2(1 )).
The equilibrium profits earned by retailers are
1, 0
1
v
2
(1 ) +
9
4(1 )
4
(1 17) +
1
2(1 (1 ))
,
1, 0
2
72
9
2
(1 )
1
+ (34 5 ) + 29(1 ) +
7
1 (1 )
,
for v/>(
4
3
+ 1/(6(1 (1 )))+ /(2(1 ))). The expression
for v/ (
4
3
+ 1/(6(1 (1))) + /(2(1 ))) can be similarly
obtained by substituting equilibrium prices into the profit
functions and is available on request.
Equilibrium Analysis. A self-matching configuration is a
Subgame perfect Nash equilibrium (SPNE) if no retailer has
the incentive to unilaterally deviate. Equivalently, for (0, 0) to
be an SPNE, retailer 1 must not have the incentive to deviate
to (1, 0). For (1, 1) to be an SPNE, retailer 2 must not have
the incentive to deviate to (1 , 0). For (1, 0) or (0, 1) to be an
SPNE the self-matching retailer must not prefer (0, 0) and the
non-self-matching retailer must not prefer (1, 1). By compar-
ing t he profits at the equilibrium prices defined above, we
can construct equilibrium regions.
Let
0
(27
p
25
2
+ 448 + 256)/(32(1 )) + 5/32. The
results in Proposition 2 focus on the region where <
0
for
clarity of exposition. In this proof, we provide an extended
analysis, including the region where
0
. Define
z
1
min((27 17)/(18(1 ))+ /(9(1 )(1 (1 ))),
7/(36(1 (1 ))) + 1/(4(1 )) + 25/18, 3/(8(1 )8
) +
5
2
),
z
2
max((27 17)/(18(1 )) + /(9(1 )(1 ·
(1 ))), 7/(36(1 (1 ))) + 1/(4(1 )) + 25/18),
z
3
1/(1 )1/(9(1 (1 ))) + 17/18.
We calculate equilibrium profits and t he applicable thresh-
olds under all subgames. Then, for v/<z
1
, the incremental
profit from self-matching for retailer 1 is positive:
1, 0
1
0, 0
1
>
0; retailer 2 prefers not to deviate as
1, 1
2
1, 0
2
< 0, so (1,0)
and (0, 1) are SPNE. For z
1
< v/<z
2
, (0, 0) is the unique equi-
librium for <
0
, as
1, 0
1
0, 0
1
< 0 while
1, 1
2
1, 0
2
< 0, and
(1,1) is the unique equilibrium for >
0
as
1, 0
1
0, 0
1
> 0
while
1, 1
2
1, 0
2
> 0. For z
2
< v/<z
3
, both (0,0) and (1,1) are
SPNE as
1, 0
1
0, 0
1
< 0 while
1, 1
2
1, 0
2
> 0, so no retailer
prefers to unilaterally deviate from either symmetric setup.
For v/>z
3
, (1, 1) is the unique SPNE as
1, 0
1
0, 0
1
> 0
while
1, 1
2
1, 0
2
> 0.
Note that for suciently large , retailers prefer to oer
symmetric self-matching policies at intermediate v. This is
because as grows, retailer 1 has an incentive to match for
lower v given that retailer 2 also matches. As the critical
threshold of v becomes lower, it may cross the threshold at
which the other retailer no longer prefers to match, yielding
an equilibrium where both retailers match for intermediate v.
To summarize, for low , as v increases, there will first be
an asymmetric solution, then (0, 0), then both (0, 0) and (1, 1),
and then uniquely (1, 1). For high , as v increases, there will
first be an asymmetric solution, then (1, 1), then both (0, 0)
and (1, 1), and then uniquely (1, 1).
Proof of Proposition 3
A comparison of profits in the (1, 0) subgame reveals that
1
1, 0
>
2
1, 0
everywhere. A comparison of profits earned by
retailer 1 in the (1, 1) subgame and in the (0, 0) subgame
reveals that
1
1,1
>
1
0, 0
if v/>
3
2
+ 1/(1 ) z
4
, which is
strictly greater than z
3
.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 19
Appendix B. Proofs for Extensions
Proof of Proposition 4
The proof of Proposition 4 proceeds just as in Proposition 2,
except with an extra parameter µ representing the fraction of
“smart” consumers, or consumers who can costlessly search
for online information while in-store. The µ segment will
be relevant for store-only undecided consumers, as they can
only claim a self-matching policy if they have access to the
Internet in-store. The remaining store-only undecided con-
sumers will be unable to claim a self-matching policy and
will have to pay the store price. We require the following
restrictions:
v > 3/2 + (µ(1 ))/(1 (1 )) ensures that all
markets are fully covered;
<1 3/(2(4 µ)) ensures that no retailer sets such a
high online price to earn zero demand from decided con-
sumers in the (1, 0) subgame;
Restriction
v <
1
+
4µ + 16 4µ + 2
12
+
3⌘
12(1 )
(1 + 2µ)
2
(1 )
2
(1 )
2
36(1 (1 ))
2
)
+
(1 + 2µ)(1 )(1 )(2 µ + 11 2µ 5)
36(1 (1 ))
ensures that no retailer wants to price exclusively for its cap-
tive segment of store-only undecided consumers and forego
all demand for store-only decided consumers;
m > v 3/2 + µ µ/(1 (1 )) ensures that no
store-only undecided consumers switch stores af ter their first
visit, and that no consumer returns home and visits the store
a second time to redeem a self-matching policy.
No Retailers Self-Match—(0, 0). The equilibrium prices un-
der (0, 0) emerge just as in Proposition 2, as mobile con-
sumers behave just as the rest of the consumers.
One Retailer Self-Matches—(1, 0). Store-only undecided
consumers who are mobile will redeem the self-matching
policy if they first visit t he store that oers the policy. Prof-
its are
1, 0
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )
·
(1 )(p
on
1
, p
s
2
)p
on
1
+
2
((1 µ)p
s
1
+ µp
on
1
)
,
1, 0
2
(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
(1 )(1 (p
on
1
, p
s
2
)) +
2
p
s
2
.
In equilibrium, the retailers set online prices
ˆ
p
on
1
((1 +
2µ)/(3(1 (1 ))) + 2(1 µ)/3) and
ˆ
p
on
2
((1 + 2µ)/(6(1
(1 ))) + (5 2µ)/6) and store prices
ˆ
p
s
1
v /2 and
ˆ
p
s
2
ˆ
p
on
2
+ ✓/(2(1 )) for v/>((1 + 2µ)/(6(1 (1 ))) +
1/(2(1 )) µ/3 +
5
6
). Otherwise,
ˆ
p
on
1
v/2 + /4 µ/2
(8µ + 9✓⌘ 6v 2✓⌘µ)/(4(4(1 ) + 4)),
ˆ
p
on
2
ˆ
p
on
1
((6 4 + µ) + 4 3)/(4(1 ) + 4), and
ˆ
p
s
1
ˆ
p
s
2
v /2. The FOCs and the binding constraint are just as in
the proof for (1, 0) in Proposition 2, except for the addition of
an extra parameter µ.
Both Retailers Self-Match—(1, 1). The retailers will earn
profits
1, 1
1
(1 (1 ))(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )
2
((1 µ)p
s
1
+ µp
on
1
),
1, 1
2
(1 (1 ))(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
+ (1 )
2
((1 µ)p
s
2
+ µp
on
2
),
and set prices p
on
1
p
on
2
(1 µ) + µ/(1 (1 )) online
and p
s
1
p
s
2
v /2 in-store.
Equilibrium Analysis. To prove the existence of the result,
we provide an example with
1
5
and
1
3
. Let
y
0
2,385µ 41(529µ
2
+ 1,408µ + 1936)
1/2
+ 7,810
4,004
,
y
1
32µ + 331
198
+
4
11(2 + µ)
,
y
2
64µ + 395
198
+
3
88(1 µ)
, y
3
32µ + 427
198
+
3
22(1 µ)
.
Comparing profits when v/<y
0
, (1, 1) is the unique SPNE.
For y
0
< v/<y
1
, (1, 0) and (0, 1) are SPNE. For y
1
< v/<
y
2
, (0, 0) is the unique equilibrium. For y
2
< v/<y
3
, (0, 0)
and (1, 1) are SPNE. For v/>y
3
, (1, 1) is the unique SPNE.
To prove the associated proposition, note that y
0
, y
1
, y
2
, and
y
3
are all increasing in µ, so that holding constant v/, an
increase in mobile consumers shrinks the equilibrium region
that admits self-matching policies.
Increasing Profits with Mobile Consumers. In the (1, 1) equi-
librium for large v,
1
5
and
1
3
, the retailers’ profits
are increasing in µ if v/<
5
2
+ 8µ/11, which is possible if
µ<0.83. Furthermore, the retailers’ profits are larger than
when µ 0 if v/<5/2 + 4µ/11, which is possible if µ<0.72.
This shows that retailer profits may increase as the fraction
of mobile consumers increases.
Proof of Proposition 5
Suppose that a multichannel retailer competes with an on-
line-only e-tailer. Assume v > 2 to ensure t hat all markets
are fully covered. Assume v < 4 and >
5
2
3/(2(1 ))
to ensure that the multichannel retailer has positive online
sales. Under (0, 0) t he retailers earn profits
0, 0
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1)p
s
1
,
0, 0
2
(1(p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
.
Taking the FOCs with respect to the prices, we solve
@
0, 0
1
@p
on
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
) + p
on
1
@(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)
@p
on
1
0 ,
@
0, 0
1
@p
s
1
(1 ) > 0, implying a corner solution.
We obtain the corresponding FOCs for retailer 2 and solve
for the equilibrium corresponding to the best responses of
both retailers. All channel-agnostic consumers will purchase
online, whereas store-only consumers will buy from the mul-
tichannel retailer’s store. The retailers will set competitive
prices online
ˆ
p
on
1
ˆ
p
on
2
, and retailer 1 will set monopoly
price in-store
ˆ
p
s
1
( v ). That is, we obtain an interior solu-
tion for online pricing, but a corner solution for the store
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
20 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
price where the multichannel retailer maximizes profits from
all captive SU consumers.
Under the (1, 0) subgame of competition between a self-
matching multichannel retailer with an e-tailer, retailers earn
profits
1, 0
1
(p
on
1
, p
on
2
)p
on
1
+ (1 )((1 )p
on
1
+ p
s
1
),
1, 0
2
(1 (p
on
1
, p
on
2
))p
on
2
.
As under (0, 0), channel-agnostic consumers will purchase
online and store-only consumers will purchase from the
multichannel retailer’s store. Store-only decided consumers
redeem the matching policy and pay the online price, whereas
store-only undecided consumers fail to redeem t he policy
and pay the store price. The retailers will set prices
ˆ
p
on
1
+
(4(1 )(1 ))/(3),
ˆ
p
on
2
+ (2(1 )(1 ))/(3),
ˆ
p
s
1
v for v > 2 + (4(1 )·(1 ))/(3). Once again, there
is an interior solution in online pricing for v suciently large
and a corner monopoly solution forthe store price. The thresh-
old for v is derived from the condition that in equilibrium
p
on
1
< v for an interior solution. That is, the online price
charged by retailer 1 cannot exceed the monopoly price for SD
consumers, or equivalently, v p
on
1
>0, ensuring that the
SD consumer farthest away from store 1 purchases in equilib-
rium for the market to remain covered. For v 2 + 4(1
(1 )/(3), this condition fails, and retailers will set prices
ˆ
p
on
1
v ,
ˆ
p
on
2
v/2,
ˆ
p
s
1
v which corresponds to a corner
solution.
Now we substitute prices into profits for the appropriate
v and identify the parameter ranges for which
1
1, 0
>
1
0, 0
to
see when retailer 1 would prefer to self-match. Suppose that
>
7
4
3/(4(1 )). Then,
1
1, 0
>
1
0, 0
if v < z
1
(
7
3
+ (8(1
(1 ))/(9)). Otherwise, if
7
4
3/(4(1 )), then
1
1, 0
>
1
0, 0
if v < z
2
3. Hence, there exists a z
0
min{z
1
, z
2
}, such
that for v < z
0
, the multichannel retailer will prefer to self-
match.
Proof of Corollary 3
A comparison of the e-tailer’s profits,
1, 0
2
0, 0
2
reveals that
it earns greater profits when the multichannel retailer oers a
self-matching policy. To see this, note that the e-tailer’s price
under (1, 0) is
ˆ
p
on
2
+ (2(1)(1 ))/(3), which is greater
than , the price it would charge under (0, 0). Also in (1, 0),
the e-tailer’s price is less than
ˆ
p
on
1
+ (4(1 )(1 ))/(3),
the online price charged by the multichannel retailer. Under
(1, 0) the e-tailer sets a higher price and earns a greater frac-
tion of demand than under (0, 0). As a result, its profits are
greater.
Suppose v 2 + (4(1 )(1 ))/(3). Then
1, 0
2
v
2
/(8) and
0, 0
2
✓⌘/2. The dierence
1, 0
2
0, 0
2
(v
2
4
2
)/(8) which is positive when v > 2, which is
the lower bound required for markets to be fully covered.
Now, suppose v > 2 + (4(1 )(1 ))/(3). Then
1, 0
2
(2(1 )2 )
2
/(18) and
0, 0
2
✓⌘/2. The dierence
1, 0
2
0, 0
2
(2(1 )(1 )(1+ 2 (1 )))/(9) is g reater
than zero whenever /(1 ) > (1 + 2)/(3), which is
always the case as >0. Hence, the e-tailer always makes
higher profits when the multichannel retailer matches.
Appendix C. Consumer Survey Across Product
Categories
We conducted a survey among N 499 individuals in the
United States using Amazon’s Mechanical Turk (mTurk) ser-
vice to identify the degree of consumer heterogeneity across
a wide range of product categories.
12
Our model and anal-
ysis depend on consumer value for a product (v), retailer
dierentiation (), and the dimensions of consumer hetero-
geneity leading to multiple segments, i.e., decided (1 )
versus undecided (), and store-only (1 ) versus channel-
agnostic ().
Operationalizing Model Characteristics
We detail how model constructs are operationalized in the
survey.
(1) Value: To operationalize the value of the product, we
asked participants to estimate how much they spent on a typ-
ical single item in t his product category. We used the median
value of the responses.
(2) Retailer Dierentiation: To operationalize the extent of
retailer dierentiation, we asked participants to estimate how
similar specific firms within a product category are with
respect to the merchandise they oer.
(3) Undecided vs. Decided Consumers: We computed the
proportion of undecided consumers by asking participants
to indicate on a 0–100 scale the extent to which they were
undecided (about specific products in a category) across a
variety of product categories and taking the average across
all responses within a category.
(4) Store vs. Channel Agnostic Consumers: To operationalize
consumer preference across channels, we asked participants
to indicate on a 0–100 scale the extent to which they would
prefer to shop in-store or online for each product category.
In Table C.1, we classify the empirically observed outcome
to the closest possible equilibrium of our model. Thus, each
market outcome is associated with one of three outcomes,
i.e., (1, 0)—Asymmetric Self-Matching, (0, 0)—Symmetric No
Self-Matching or (1, 1)—Symmetric Self-Matching.
Figure C.1 illustrates a plot of multichannel retail cate-
gories based on how survey participants characterized them
along the various heterogeneity dimensions. The values in
parentheses in Figure C.1 are taken from Table C.1. There
are a few observations that deserve attention here. First, the
proportion of undecided participants displays a considerable
range, from 20% for pet supply products to almost 60%
for apparel. Second, we find that participants also display
a range of channel preferences, from home improvement,
where a large majority prefer to shop in store, to electron-
ics, where about half prefer to shop online. Third, when
Table C.1. Self-Matching Outcomes
Market Empirical outcome
Pet supply (0, 1)
Apparel (0, 0)
Department (low) (0, 0)
Department (upscale) (1, 1)
Oce supply (1, 1)
Home improvement (1, 1)
Electronics (1, 1)
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 21
Figure C.1. (Color online) Consumer Characteristics and
Market Outcomes
0 10 20 30 40 50
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
Market characteristics
(a) Channel/Decision stage
Preference for channel (0: Store, 100: Online)
(b) Value/Channel
Proportion of undecided
Pet supply
Electronics
Home improvement
Apparel
Upscale department
Low department
Office supply
(1, 0)
(1,1)
(1,1)
(0, 0)
(1,1)
(0,0)
(1,1)
0 10 20 30 40 50
0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
Market characteristics
Preference for channel (0: Store, 100: Online)
Value/Differentiation
Pet supply
Electronics
Home improvement
Apparel
Upscale department
Low department
Office supply
(1, 0)
(1,1)
(1,1)
(0, 0)
(1,1)
(0, 0)
(1,1)
we plot channel preference versus the proportion of unde-
cided consumers (participants) for each category, we find
that there is a significant variation along both dimensions,
with home improvement and pet supplies featuring more
consumers who prefer store purchases, while being rela-
tively more decided than undecided. The apparel product
category, on the other hand, is characterized by significantly
more undecided consumers (60%), and demonstrates a
moderate preference for shopping in store. Based on the
survey, we find evidence of significant heterogeneity in
consumer (participant) preferences and behavior across a
wide range of product categories, lending credibility to our
model tenets. Furthermore, in the value/dierentiation ver-
sus channel preference plot (Figure C.1(b)), the equilibrium
regions obtained in Proposition 2 are largely consistent with
the policies observed in practice.
Appendix D. Self-Matching Policies in Practice
Below we list the self-matching policies of several popu-
lar retailers. We obtained these from retailers’ websites on
January 14, 2016 and verified them by calling store locations
to inquire about matching the website price (if lower).
Self-Matching Retailers
13
Best Buy: “We match BestBuy.com prices on in-store pur-
chases”
Also matches online and local competitors.
http://www.bestbuy.com/site/help-topics/best-buy
-low-price-guarantee/pcmcat297300050000.c?idpcmcat297
300050000.
Sears: “If you find a lower price on an identical brand and
model number from another Sears branded non-outlet retail
format or website, Sears will match that price for up to 7 days
after the date of your purchase.
Also matches online and local competitors.
http://www.sears.com/cspricematch/nb-100000000
022522.
Staples: “If you purchase an item from Staples and tell us
within 14 days that you found that item at a lower price in
our stores or at staples.com, we’ll refund the dierence.
Also matches Amazon.com and any retailer who sells
products in retail stores and online under the same brand
name.
http://www.staples.com/sbd/content/help-center/
pricing-and-promotions.html.
Oce Depot: “If you find a lower price on a new identical
item on OceDepot.com or OceMax.com at t he time of
purchase or within 14 days of your purchase, show us the
lower price and Oce Depot or OceMax stores will match
the price or refund you the dierence.
Also matches Amazon.com and any retailer who sells
products in retail stores and online under the same brand
name.
http://www.ocedepot.com/renderStaticPage.do?
file/customerservice/lowPrice.jsp.
Toys “R” Us: “We will match Toysrus.com and Babies-
rus.com online pricing in our stores.
Also matches online and local competitors.
http://www.toysrus.com/shop/index.jsp?categoryId
11949070.
Petsmart: Website price will be honored in store.
Obtained from customer service at 203-937-2749.
Lowe’s: Website price will be honored in store.
Obtained from customer service at 1-800-445-6937.
Home Depot: Website price will be honored in store.
Obtained from customer service at 1-800-466-3337.
Retailers who do not Self-Match
JCPenney: All online and mobile pricing, promotions,
advertisements, or oers, including from jcp, are excluded
from our price matching policy.”
Matches local competitors.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
22 Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS
http://www.jcpenney.com/dotcom/jsp/customer
service/serviceContent.jsp?pageIdpg40014800010.
Macy’s: “macys.com and Macy’s stores operate separately.
This means that the products and prices oered at each may
be dierent.
Does not match competitors.
https://customerservice.macys.com/app/answers/
detail/a_id/14/
~
/pricing-policy-for-online-merchandise.
Urban Outfitters: “While merchandise oered on-line at
UrbanOutfitters.com will usually be priced the same as mer-
chandise oered at our aliate Urban Outfitters stores, in
some cases, Urban Outfitters stores may have dierent prices
or promotional events at dierent times.”
Does not state whether it matches competitors.
http://www.urbanoutfitters.com/urban/help/terms
_of_use.jsp.
Petco: ...Petco and Unleashed by Petco stores do not
match the prices of unleashedbypetco.com, petco.com or
other online sellers and/or websites.
Does not match competitor websites but does match
local competitor stores.
https://www.petco.com/content/petco/PetcoStore/
en_US/pet-services/help/help-policies-terms.html#price
-matching.
Endnotes
1
A webpage printout or a mobile screenshot of the webpage usu-
ally suces as appropriate evidence. Policies allowing self-matching
in the other direction, i.e., allowing web customers to match store
prices, are rarely observed in practice as prices online are typically
lower than in-store (Reda 2012, Mulpuru 2013).
2
See Appendix D for examples of self-matching policies from retailer
websites.
3
See Wahba (2014).
4
More generally, the product category is suciently large and varied
to make forming accurate expectations of prices more costly than
simply visiting the preferred store.
5
In the baseline model, consumers cannot access online prices at the
store, although we examine this possibility in Section 5 by modeling
a segment of consumers with mobile Internet access.
6
The other asymmetric equilibrium (0, 1) is obtained by relabeling
the retailers.
7
Formally, we require bounds on v and , which are detailed in the
appendix. In the Electronic Supplement we explore a setting where
the market is not fully covered but can expand.
8
Note that qualitatively similar results hold if a single retailer is
located at the center of the unit segment.
9
If v/ is suciently low in the main model, retailers no longer
compete for consumers at the center, and act essentially like monop-
olists. The results of Proposition 1 apply and no retailer will choose
to self-match.
10
We also acknowledge t hat the competitive market forces in some
of these industries, e.g., oce supplies, may be evolving.
11
To see this, consider the case of an AD consumer. A consumer at x
purchases online if v p
on
1
|x
1
2
|0. In other words, consumers
at x
1
2
(v p
on
1
)/ for x
1
2
and at x
1
2
+ (v p
on
1
)/ for x
1
2
purchase and the remainder do not, leading to a total demand
of 2((v p
on
1
)/) for the monopolist from AD consumers. For an
interior solution to exist (the market is not completely served) it
must be the case that 2(( v p
on
1
)/) < 1, or p
on
1
> v /2. However,
solving the optimization problem for the monopolist (maximizing
2((v p
on
1
)/)p
on
1
) will yield a price of
v
2
, and v/2 > v /2 if and only
if v <. A similar logic follows for the other segments. Hence, the
condition v >ensures that the monopolist serves t he entire market.
12
We filtered out participants who did not pass a number of standard
validation checks including multiple attention checks and minimum
time to complete the survey, for a final sample of N 430 individual
responses.
13
All links were accessed in January 2016.
References
Balasubramanian S (1998) Mail versus mall: A strategic analysis of
competition between direct marketers and conventional retail-
ers. Marketing Sci. 17(3):181–195.
Bustillo M, Lawton C (2009) Best Buy expands private-label brands.
Wall Street Journal (April 27), http://online.wsj.com/article/
SB124078866665357525.html.
Chen Y, Narasimhan C, Zhang Z (2001) Consumer heterogene-
ity and competitive price-matching guarantees. Marketing Sci.
20(3):300–314.
Cooper T (1986) Most-favored-customer pricing and tacit collusion.
RAND J. Econom. 17(3):377–388.
Corts K (1998) Third-degree price discrimination in oligopoly: All-
out competition and strategic commitment. RAND J. Econom.
29(2):306–323.
Coughlan A, Shaer G (2009) Price-matching guarantees, retail
competition, and product-line assortment. Marketing Sci. 28(3):
580–588.
Desai PS, Purohit D (2004) Let me talk to my manager: Haggling in
a competitive environment. Marketing Sci. 23(2):219–233.
Diamond PA (1971) A model of price adjustment. J. Econom. Theory
3(2):156–168.
eMarketer (2013) Dynamic pricing helps keep pace with savvy
consumers. (May 17), https://www.emarketer.com/Article/
Dynamic-Pricing-Helps-Keep-Pace-with-Savvy-Consumers/100
9897.
Fiorletta A (2013) Inconsistent pricing across channels remains
a key challenge for retailers. Retail Touchpoints (January 28),
http://www.retailtouchpoints.com/shopper-engagement/2245
-inconsistent-pricing-across-channels-remains-a-key-challenge
-for-retailers.
Grewal D, Janakiraman R, Kalyanam K, Kannan P, Ratchford B,
Song R, Tolerico S (2010) Strategic online and oine retail
pricing: A review and research agenda. J. Interactive Marketing
24(2):138–154.
Holmes T (1989) The eects of third-degree price discrimination in
oligopoly. Amer. Econom. Rev. 79(1):244–250.
Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econom. J. 39(153):41–57.
Hviid M, Shaer G (1999) Hassle costs: The achilles’ heel of
price-matching guarantees. J. Econom. Management Strategy 8(4):
489–521.
Jiang B, Jerath K, Srinivasan K (2011) Firm strategies in the “mid tail”
of platform-based retailing. Marketing Sci. 30(5):757–775.
Liu L, Dukes A (2013) Consideration set formation with multiprod-
uct firms: The case of within-firm and across-firm evaluation
costs. Management Sci. 59(8):1871–1886.
Liu Y, Gupta S, Zhang Z (2006) Note on self-restraint as an online
entry-deterrence strategy. Management Sci. 52(11):1799–1809.
Mattioli D (2011) Retailers try to thwart price apps. Wall
Street Journal (December 23), http://online.wsj.com/article/
SB10001424052970203686204577114901480554444.html.
Mehra A, Kumar S, Raju J (2013) “Showrooming” and the competi-
tion between store and online retailers. Working paper, Indian
School of Business, Hyderabad, India.
Mohammed R (2013) Is Target’s price matching policy a mistake?
Harvard Bus. Rev. (January 15), http://blogs.hbr.org/cs/2013/
01/is_targets_price_matching_poli.html.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.
Kireyev, Kumar, and Ofek: Match Your Own Price?
Marketing Science, Articles in Advance, pp. 1–23, © 2017 INFORMS 23
Moorthy S, Winter R (2006) Price-matching guarantees. RAND J.
Econom. 37(2):449–465.
Moorthy S, Zhang X (2006) Price matching by vertically dieren-
tiated retailers: Theory and evidence. J. Marketing Res. 43(2):
156–167.
Mulpuru S (2010) The state of retailing online 2010: Key metrics
and multichannel and global strategies. Forrester Res. (Octo-
ber 28), https://www.forrester.com/report/The+State+Of+
Retailing+Online+2010+Key+Metrics+And+Multichannel+And
+Global+Strategies//E-RES57389.
Mulpuru S (2012) Our cross-channel numbers show “showroom-
ing” could be overblown. Forrester Res. (June 12), http://blogs
.forrester.com/sucharita_mulpuru/12-06-12-our_cross_channel
_numbers_show_showrooming_could_be_overblown.
Mulpuru S (2013) U.S. cross-channel retail forecast, 2012 to
2017. Forrester Res. (October 29), https://www.forrester.com/
report/US+CrossChannel+Retail+Forecast+2012+To+2017/-/
E-RES105461.
Nalca A, Boyaci T, Ray S (2010) Competitive price-matching guaran-
tees under imperfect store availability. Quant. Marketing Econom.
8(3):275–300.
Neslin S, Grewal D, Leghorn R, Shankar V, Teerling M, Thomas J,
Verhoef P (2006) Challenges and opportunities in multichannel
customer management. J. Service Res. 9(2):95–112.
Ofek E, Katona Z, Sarvary M (2011) Bricks and clicks: The impact
of product returns on the strategies of multichannel retailers.
Marketing Sci. 30(1):42–60.
Reda S (2012) Pricing transparency. NRF (January 31), https://
nrf.com/news/retail-trends/pricing-transparency.
Salop S (1986) Practices that (credibly) facilitate oligopoly co-
ordination. Stiglitz J, Mathewson F, eds. New Developments in
the Analysis of Market Structure (MIT Press, Cambridge, MA),
265–290.
Shin J (2007) How does free riding on customer service aect com-
petition? Marketing Sci. 26(4):488–503.
Thisse J, Vives X (1988) On the strategic choice of spatial price policy.
Amer. Econom. Rev. 78(1):122–137.
Verhoef PC, Kannan P, Inman JJ (2015) From multi-channel retailing
to omni-channel retailing: Introduction to the special issue on
multi-channel retailing. J. Retailing 91(2):174–181.
Wahba P (2014) J.C. Penney’s secret comeback sauce? Its own
brands. Fortune (December 22), http://fortune.com/2014/12/
22/jc-penney-private-label/.
Yoo WS, Lee E (2011) Internet channel entry: A strategic analysis of
mixed channel structures. Marketing Sci. 30(1):29–41.
Zhang X (2009) Retailers’ multichannel and price advertising strate-
gies. Marketing Sci. 28(6):1080–1094.
Zhang Z (1995) Price-matching policy and the principle of minimum
dierentiation. J. Indust. Econom. 43(3):287–299.
Downloaded from informs.org by [128.36.7.68] on 18 September 2017, at 11:56 . For personal use only, all rights reserved.