What is the natural rate of unemployment?
Ellen R. Rissman
The unemployment rate is the composite
of three distinct types of unemployment: fric-
tional, cyclical, and structural. This fact poses
a potentially serious problem for government
policymakers because high unemployment rates
are not necessarily indicative of a slack econ-
omy. Structural change as well as cyclical fac-
tors affect the unemployment rate. If
policymakers are not able to distinguish higher
unemployment rates due to a change in the
structure of employment from higher unem-
ployment rates due to a weak economy, then
they run the risk of implementing expansionary
policies at the wrong time, thereby creating or
adding to inflationary pressures. Hence, to
adequately gauge the state of the economy, it
is necessary to know what portion of the cur-
rent unemployment rate is due to purely cy-
clical phenomena as opposed to structural and
frictional.
The natural rate of unemployment is de-
fined simply as the rate of unemployment that
is compatible with a steady inflation rate. The
natural rate can therefore be thought of as the
rate of unemployment that would occur in the
absence of cyclical fluctuations. In other words
the natural rate is essentially the sum of struc-
tural and frictional unemployment. Because
structural and institutional factors change over
time, the natural rate of unemployment will
also vary. However, the need to understand
the determinants of the natural rate and its re-
lation to the actual rate of unemployment is
quite real as the cost of error may be acceler-
ating inflation or deflation.
The purpose of this article is to answer the
question: What is the natural rate of unem-
ployment? The answer relies heavily on the pi-
oneering work of Lilien (1982) and is in two
parts. First, a working definition of the natural
rate of unemployment is developed. Second,
with this definition, estimates of the natural
rate of unemployment are calculated.
The analysis indicates that the natural
rate of unemployment has been quite variable
over the last 27 years, reaching a high of 7.01
percent in the third quarter of 1981 and at-
taining a low of 3.48 percent in the first quarter
of 1966. But to understand the performance
of the economy, it is the difference between the
natural rate and actual rate of unemployment
that is significant. This difference has varied
widely over time. From 1958 through 1966 the
natural rate was well below the actual; the re-
verse held from 1967 to 1973. From 1974
through 1976 the actual rate again exceeded
the natural rate although in more recent years
the reverse appears once more to be the case.
Because the difference between the nat-
ural and actual rates of unemployment is
thought to be indicative of the degree of
tightness in the labor market, this measure
should be positively correlated with the in-
flation rate. Indeed, the correlation coefficient
between the difference and the inflation rate
as measured by the Consumer Price Index is
0.46. This compares with an almost zero cor-
relation of inflation with the actual unemploy-
ment rate.
Categories of unemployment
In general it is useful to distinguish con-
ceptually among three distinct types of unem-
ployment in analyzing the historical pattern of
the unemployment rate.' First, there is fric-
tional unemployment. Frictional unemploy-
ment arises as a result of the normal labor
turnover that occurs in a healthy dynamic
economy. At any given time employed workers
change jobs, lose jobs, or leave the labor force.
Similarly, unemployed workers may find em-
ployment or may decide to stop seeking em-
ployment, while still others may enter or
reenter the labor force. Even in the best of
times there is some unemployment that arises
from this dynamic friction in the economy.
The type of unemployment that is per-
haps perceived and felt most acutely is cyclical
unemployment. As its name suggests, it is the
type of unemployment that is associated with
business cycles. Decreases in aggregate de-
mand such as occur during recessions cause a
general overall decline in labor demand. The
real wage rate is relatively unresponsive to
Ellen R. Rissman is an economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago.
federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
3
these changing conditions, that is, real wages
do not decline as labor demand declines.
2
As a
result, unemployment occurs. If real wages
were free to adjust to these changed conditions
in the labor market, then recessions would not
produce any noticeable increase in the unem-
ployment rate. Cyclical unemployment is
temporary and when demand conditions return
to their previous level, the excess labor supply
disappears. Even permanent declines in ag-
gregate demand result in only temporary un-
employment because sooner or later wages in
a competitive economy must adjust so as to
equate labor supply and labor demand, though
now at a lower equilibrium wage rate.
The third type of unemployment is prob-
ably the least understood and also the most
traumatic to endure. Unlike cyclical
unemployment, structural unemployment is the
result of shifts in the
relative
demand for differ-
ent types of labor. Whether these relative shifts
in labor demand are caused by changes in rel-
ative factor prices (e.g., an oil price shock),
technological innovations, changes in tastes
and preferences, or perhaps changes in institu-
tional or other characteristics of the economy,
is not important. The essential point is that as
labor demand for one type of labor falls relative
to another, a temporary mismatch occurs be-
tween the skills that employers desire and those
that the work force actually possesses. This
produces only temporary unemployment be-
cause in time those who are structurally unem-
ployed will either retrain to find employment
in the now higher labor demand industries, re-
locate to find jobs requiring the types of skills
they already have, or perhaps leave the labor
force altogether, in which case they are not
counted as unemployed. How long this process
takes depends upon the costs of education, the
costs associated with relocating or finding em-
ployment further from one's original location,
and the costs of job search, and, of course, ad-
ditional opportunity and psychological costs.
In terms of these three components, the
natural rate of unemployment is simply the rate
that would occur in the absence of cyclical
fluctuations. It is the sum of frictional and
structural unemployment.
Historical perspective
Figure 1 presents the civilian unemploy-
ment rate quarterly from 1948 through 1985
with the periods between business cycle peaks
and troughs shaded for reference. There ap-
pear to be three distinct phases. The decade
of the 1950s is characterized by three re-
cessions, with unemployment peaking at each
economic downturn. Between these periods,
the unemployment rate hovered somewhere
between four and five percent. Even when the
unemployment rate reached its highest value
of 7.37 percent, it was substantially below the
two-digit unemployment rates of recent years.
The decade of the 1960s was one of eco-
nomic growth with no major recessions re-
corded after 1961. And as a result, the
unemployment rate drifted downwards from a
high at the depth of the recession of 7.00 per-
cent to a low in 1969 of 3.40 percent.
Unsurprisingly, structural unemployment
was not an issue at this time. Indeed, the pat-
tern of unemployment is very well explained
by two components: cyclical and frictional.
The business cycles of the 1950s and early
1960s attest to the significance of the cyclical
element, while the relatively economically calm
remainder of the 1960s underscores the impor-
tance of frictional unemployment.
Economists and policymakers of the time
alike recommended a seemingly reasonable
unemployment rate target for policy of around
three percent. This three percent level was
called, with perhaps unconscious irony, the full
employment rate of unemployment. While the
nomenclature is unfortunate, the term was
meant to indicate the level of unemployment
that would occur in the absence of cyclical
factors. From the perspective of the 1950s
.
and
1960s, then, the full employment level of un-
Figure 1
Civilian unemployment rate
A111111111111111111111111111111111'111
1
1
949 '53
'57
'61
'65
'69
'73
'77
'81
'85
4
Economic Perspectives
age
ti
percent
0.77
'85
5
0.66
0.55
0.44
0.33
0.22
0.11
0.00
011
employment was essentially the frictional level
of unemployment.
The 1970s and 1980s to date exhibit a
much different unemployment rate pattern.
Over this time the unemployment rate rose
from a low of 4.17 percent in the first quarter
of 1970 to a high of 10.60 percent in the fourth
quarter of 1982. As in previous years, the un-
employment rate responded to cyclical factors,
peaking in the trough of each of the four major
recessions. But, the unemployment rate ap-
pears to be trending upwards during the period
so that the average unemployment rate from
1970 through 1985 was 6.94 percent as com-
pared to 4.51 percent and 4.78 percent respec-
tively for the 1950s and 1960s. In addition, the
unemployment rate appears to be much more
volatile in these later years: The calculated
standard deviation is 1.50, compared to stan-
dard deviations of 1.28 and 1.08 in the two
earlier decades.
Demographic change
This abrupt change in the pattern exhib-
ited by the unemployment rate suggests that
there were factors involved other than merely
frictional and cyclical unemployment. One
possible explanation is that the underlying la-
bor force demographics changed, thereby ad-
versely affecting the unemployment rate.
Specifically, the labor force composition
changed over the 1970s relative to what it was
in the 1960s in such a way that the labor force
now contains a significantly higher proportion
of individuals subject to higher unemployment
rates, such as nonwhites, females, and youths.
A simple way of testing the effects of the
changing demographic composition of the la-
bor force on the unemployment rate is to com-
pare the actual civilian unemployment rate
(UR) with a fixed-weight unemployment rate
(WUR). Specifically, the unemployment rate
is calculated as:
URt =
Eyi
1
URi
a
i = 1, . .,1
[1]
:=1
where
UR,
is the unemployment rate at time
1,
i
indexes the I demographic groups, y
i
, is the
fraction of the total labor force in group
i
at
time
t,
and the sum of the y
u
's equals one.
The fixed-weight unemployment rate at
time
t
is calculated as:
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
WUR, =
yip UR
i
,
i = 1, . .
.,/
[2]
i=
1
where
T
is some pre-assigned base period.
Thus, the fixed-weight unemployment rate
computes what the civilian unemployment rate
would have been if the demographic composi-
tion of the labor force had remained as it was
in base period
T.
Figure 2 plots the differences between the
actual quarterly unemployment rate and vari-
ous fixed-weight measures where the base pe-
riod
T
is selected to be the first quarter of
1960.
3
Positive values indicate that the demo-
graphic changes that have occurred relative to
the first quarter of 1960 unfavorably affect the
unemployment rate while negative values indi-
cate that the unemployment rate would have
been higher if the demographic composition of
the labor force had been the same as in the base
period. The calculations were done for race,
sex and age categories.
4
As is obvious from Figure 2, the increase
in the proportion of females, nonwhites, and
young people in the labor force resulted in a
small increase in the unemployment rate. The
most important effect occurred as a result of
changes in the age distribution. At its peak in
1975, the changing age distribution contributed
around three quarters of a percentage point to
the overall unemployment rate. However, this
effect has been decreasing as the labor force has
aged.
In contrast, the changing racial composi-
tion of the labor force tended to increase the
Figure 2
Effect of changing demographics on
the unemployment rate
unemployment rate at an accelerating rate over
the 1970s and early 1980s, reaching its maxi-
mum effect in 1983. But race never contributes
more than one quarter of a percentage point to
the aggregate unemployment rate.
Finally, the increased labor force partic-
ipation of women relative to 1960 has for the
most part adversely affected the unemployment
rate, contributing approximately an additional
two tenths of a percentage point in 1978.
However, since 1979 the relation between the
sex composition of the labor force and the un-
employment rate has become less marked due
to a decline in the unemployment rate of fe-
males relative to males.
This change is not necessarily attributable
to lower levels of sex discrimination. An alter-
native explanation may be that women are
clustered in jobs that are relatively more pro-
tected from market forces. For example, blue
collar jobs are more frequently filled by men
than women. Those blue collar jobs that are
located in declining industries would contribute
to a higher unemployment rate for males than
for females, all other things equal.
Thus, it seems that the changing demo-
graphic composition of the labor force has re-
sulted in an increase in the civilian
unemployment rate since 1960, but the magni-
tude of the effect is quite modest—adding less
than one percentage point to the total unem-
ployment rate. Even after controlling for
changes in the demographic composition of the
labor force, the unemployment rate of the
1970s and early 1980s is still significantly
higher and more volatile than in the previous
two decades.
Changing industrial composition
Just as the demographic distribution (and
possibly the geographic distribution) of the la-
bor force provides clues to analyzing the more
recent behavior of the unemployment rate, the
distribution of employment across industries
also plays a role. It is the changes in the dis-
tribution of employment across industries that
is most closely related to the concept of struc-
tural unemployment. As noted previously,
structural unemployment arises due to relative
shifts in the demand for different types of labor
causing a period of economic adjustment dur-
ing which time some displaced labor will be
temporarily unemployed. Changes in the rela-
tive demands for labor will be accompanied by
changes in the distribution of employment
across industries.
Perhaps the most prominent movement in
the employment profile in recent history is the
change of the private economy from one based
upon manufacturing and other traditional in-
dustries to one based upon services and
service-related industries.' Figure 3 presents
this trend for selected industries, and prompts
important observations. First, the decline in
manufacturing and concurrent rise in the share
of employment in services are not recent phe-
nomena. The graph shows that these adjust-
ments have been occurring almost continuously
throughout the post-World War II period.
Secondly, even within manufacturing
there are notable differences between the be-
havior of employment shares in durable and
nondurable goods. The decline in nondurable
goods has proceeded much more smoothly than
the decline in employment share in durable
manufacturing.
This steady decline in the relative impor-
tance of nondurable manufacturing is not nec-
essarily an indication of structural change in
the sense that it documents the ebb and flow
of the fortunes of the industry in question.
The
historical pattern is also consistent with a steady
stream of technological innovation which enables pro-
duction to remain unchanged while employment levels
decline.
While the steady decline in employ-
ment share is almost certain to contribute to
the flow of unemployment, it may well be that
the unemployment generated is much less in
volume and of shorter duration than that which
would occur in industries experiencing a more
sporadic, volatile decline such as durable man-
ufacturing. The reason is that rational workers
are more likely to be able to predict and
therefore cushion or even avoid the blow of
unemployment altogether by preparing for the
event sufficiently in advance.
The third observation concerning the
patterns seen in Figure 3 pertains to the effect
of business cycles on the distribution of em-
ployment across industries. Recessions clearly
and consistently are associated with declines in
employment share in durable goods manufac-
turing. It is well known that business cycles
have a differential impact across industries, af-
fecting some more adversely than others.
6
Just
why this occurs depends upon the nature of the
demand for the good as well as the costs of in-
6
Economic
Perspectives
Figure 3
Share of total employment in
selected industries
percent
30 — P T
25
20
15
10
5
0
111111111111111111111111111111111111.■11
1947
'55
'63
'71
'79
'85
ventorying. If the good is viewed as a luxury
item or requires a relatively large expenditure,
then purchases are more likely to be postponed
during periods of low aggregate demand, when
discretionary income falls. For example, hous-
ing starts and new construction are particularly
susceptible to changes in the economic outlook.
In addition, those industries with high inven-
tory costs are less able to smooth production
and are therefore more susceptible to the
vagaries of the market.
The post-World War II era has seen
considerable change in the distribution of em-
ployment across industries. Such shifts in em-
ployment are likely to generate unemployment
temporarily as displaced workers search for
employment. Large movements in employ-
ment across industrial sectors are likely to be
associated with temporary increases in the un-
employment rate because these movements
signify a change in the underlying structure of
the economy. However, change in and of itself
does not cause unemployment. The unem-
ployment arises because of friction or inertia in
the economy which make it difficult for indi-
viduals to adapt instantaneously. Given these
frictions, the larger is the flow of workers into
and out of the various industries, the more
likely it is that a larger volume of unemploy-
ment will be generated.
One way of measuring these flows is to
define a variable ol where:
I
2
1
(
It
sit-1 [git
gt.1
2
[3]
:=1
sa is the share of total employment in industry
i
at time t,
g„ is the growth rate of employment
in the ith industry between period
t
and period
t
— 1, and I is the number of industries. Thus,
of
is the weighted sum of squared deviations of
industry growth from average aggregate
growth where the weights are given by the
employment share of the ith industry.
This measure captures those employment
flows that are associated with changes in the
distribution of employment across industries
and not those changes in employment that oc-
cur as a result of economic growth. Further-
more, those industries experiencing a large
deviation in employment growth relative to the
average growth rate of employment are given
more weight in the calculation due to the
squaring of the term in parentheses. Such a
weighting scheme is appropriate if, for exam-
ple, large deviations in employment growth
from the average are associated with dispro-
portionately large increases in unemployment.
For further details on the interpretation of 491
see Box,
Measuring employment flows.
Figure 4 displays the measure of employ-
ment adjustment
a?
from the first quarter of
1947 through 1985.
7
There appear to be many
periods of rapid employment adjustment across
industries during the post-war period. Fre-
quently, these adjustments are coincidental
with business cycles as noted in the preceding
discussion of industry employment shares. The
period from 1947 to 1960 is marked by three
episodes of employment adjustment corre-
sponding roughly with the recessions in 1950,
1954, and 1958. The more stable 1960s exhibit
very little change in the distribution of em-
ployment across industries. The 1970s and
early 1980s in contrast indicate a pronounced
change in employment shares occurred in late
1970 and again in 1975 and 1978. The 1980s
are surprisingly stable in comparison to the ex-
perience of the 1970s, providing preliminary
evidence that structural change was perhaps
not a major contributing factor to the histor-
ically high unemployment observed in the 1982
recession.
The effect of employment adjustment
across industries on the civilian age-weighted
unemployment rate is analyzed over the period
from 1954 through the third quarter of 1985.
8
The results of the analysis are found in Table
1, which presents the estimates and associated
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
7
.00090 P T
A
.00000
,......„„„„
.00075
.00060
.00045
.00030
.00015
Figure 4
Measure of employment adjustment
across industries
1947
'55
'63
standard errors of the parameters of interest as
well as some additional descriptive statistics.
Other variables included in the analysis
are measures of unanticipated changes in real
Gross National Production (GNP) and unan-
ticipated money growth (M). Unanticipated
real GNP is calculated as the residuals from the
estimated ARIMA process generating real
GNP where the estimates are obtained by the
maximum likelihood method. Unanticipated
money growth is computed as discussed in
Barro (1978).
Columns (1) through (3) of Table 1 pre-
sent estimates of ordinary least squares re-
gressions on various sets of variables including
two lagged dependent variables.
9
All three models reported in Table 1 in-
dicate that unanticipated movements in real
Gross National Product are negatively associ-
ated with the age-weighted unemployment
rate. Thus, realizations of real GNP above
trend tend to decrease the unemployment rate
while realizations below trend tend to increase
the unemployment rate.
Intuition suggests that unanticipated
money growth should also be negatively asso-
ciated with the unemployment rate if unantic-
ipated positive changes in monetary growth
signal expansionary monetary policy. As seen
in columns (2) and (3) of Table 1, the coeffi-
cient on unanticipated money growth is nega-
tive only for current realizations and positive
for lagged values. However, the magnitude of
the effect is imprecisely determined as seen by
the large associated standard errors.
Finally, the inclusion of current and
lagged values of the measure of employment
Table 1
The effect of employment adjustment
on the unemployment rate
(1)
(2)
(3)
GNP
t
-0.018
-0.019
-0.016
(0.002)
(0.002)
(0.002)
GNP
t
_i
-0.011
-0.012
-0.008
(0.003)
(0.003)
(0.003)
GNP
t_2
-0.005
-0.005
-0.004
(0.002)
(0.003)
(0.002)
Mt
-3.215
-2.551
(3.556)
(3.312)
Mt-1
2.444
1.054
(3.700)
(3.417)
Mt-2
3.313
2.721
(3.946)
(3.619)
a
t
790.443
(212.599)
393.051
(234.715)
/VI
a
t-2
-387.709
(234.671)
106.700
(215.610)
t-4
a
t-4
-603.343
(199.532)
UR
t
_i
1.387
1.385
1.308
(0.074)
(0.076)
(0.086)
UR
t
_2
-0.406
-0.402
-0.319
(0.076)
(0.079)
(0.086)
C
0.093
0.078
0.030
(0.087)
(0.091)
(0.083)
R
2
0.976
0.977
0.982
Q
5.74
5.43
3.80
adjustment has a clear and significant effect on
the unemployment rate. Increases in the
amount of interindustry employment adjust-
ment have an initial adverse affect upon the
unemployment rate, as expected. Thus, the
larger are the changes in the distribution of
employment across industries, the higher is the
unemployment rate. The long term effects of
such shifts in employment are not immediately
obvious, however, due to the inclusion of the
two lagged dependent variables in the re-
gression model. The difficulty arises because
current changes in o
-2
affect not only the cur-
rent unemployment rate but also future unem-
I ,
1 1 I
11
7
1
'79
'85
8
Economic Perspectives
Measuring employment flows
To further motivate the use of
711 ,
defined in equation [3], let
e„
be employ-
ment in industry
i
at time
t
and let
E e“
be the total level of employment
i=i
in the economy at time
t.
The change in
the number of people employed in indus-
try
i
between periods
t
and
t — 1 is simply
e, —
However, employment changes
can occur for two reasons: economic
growth and shifts in the underlying indus-
trial composition of employment. For
purposes of measuring structural change
and relating structural change to the un-
employment rate, adjustments in employ-
ment due to shifts in the employment
distribution across industries alone are of
interest. Thus, the expression
e, — s
ii
_
l
e
t
is
simply the difference between employment
in industry
i
at time
t
and the amount of
employment in industry
i
that would have
occurred at time
t
if the
Ph
industry had
grown at the same rate as the aggregate
economy, i.e. the employment share of in-
dustry
i
had remained unchanged. Obvi-
ously, if no change in employment share
had occurred, then the expression
e
u
s
it
e,
equals zero. Similarly, if
e, — s
tt
_
i
e,
is posi-
tive (negative), then the
Ph
industry's em-
ployment share is rising (falling).
The change in employment attribut-
able solely to changes in employment
share and not economic growth can be re-
written in terms of growth rates as
e„._
1
(A, —A) . Since the unemployment rate
is assumed to respond to the magnitude
and not the direction of employment
changes, the total volume of employment
flows attributable to shifts in the distrib-
ution of employment is simply calculated
as
Ee,_, I
g
it
A I which is proportional to
i=1
E
I
g„ —
g
t
1 .
Finally, by squaring the
r=1
amount within the absolute value signs,
the original expression for
a?
results.
As discussed briefly in the text, by
squaring g
it
—A
I those industries expe-
riencing relatively large deviations of
employment growth from the aggregate
are given more weight in the calculation.
Since structural shifts of large magni-
tudes are thought to have a dispropor-
tionately large impact upon the
unemployment rate, such a weighting
scheme is appropriate.
ployment rates. Simulations show that the
maximum effect of an increase in the volume
of interindustry employment changes is felt af-
ter a one-quarter lag, damping thereafter.
It should be noted that while the coeffi-
cient estimates on current and lagged values of
are quite large in magnitude, the actual
values of
a2
are relatively small, with an aver-
age value over the entire time period of
1.3x10
-4
. If, for example, a one standard de-
viation increase in
6
2
occurred at time 0, the
unemployment rate would rise by only 0.20
percent in the first quarter, 0.36 percent in the
second quarter, and 0.16 percent after one
year.
While the evidence reported in Table 1
suggests that the volume of interindustry
movement of employees is positively related to
the unemployment rate, the interpretation that
the associated movements in the unemploy-
ment rate are due to structural change is not
that easily justified. Thus, drawing inferences
about structural unemployment or the natural
rate of unemployment from the results found in
Table 1 is inappropriate. The difficulty arises
because of the simultaneous effect of cyclical
and structural factors on employment flows.
As illustrated in Figure 3, the ebb and flow of
employment shares is dependent upon the stage
of the business cycle. In durable manufactur-
ing recessions are invariably associated with
declining employment shares and therefore a
greater amount of employment adjustment.
The problem therefore is to develop a measure
that distinguishes employment flows attribut-
able only to structural factors from employ-
ment flows attributable to purely cyclical
factors.
federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
9
'61
'65
'69
'73
'77
'81
0.03
0.02
0.01
0.00
Structural change
There are a variety of ways to extract the
purely cyclical effect on the distribution of em-
ployment across industries from the purely
structural. These techniques all rely upon an
assumption that cyclical changes in employ-
ment are temporary while structural changes
are more or less permanent by definition.
In attempting to eliminate the effect of
cyclical factors on the distribution of employ-
ment across industries, calculations can proceed
along one of two lines. A measure of the vari-
ability of employment shares (or possibly em-
ployment growth) across industries can be
calculated first and then decomposed into a
permanent (structural) component and a tem-
porary (cyclical) one. Alternatively, the em-
ployment share or level in each industry is
decomposed into its permanent and cyclical el-
ements and then, using only the permanent
portion, a single measure of permanent change
in employment distribution is devised. The
first approach, while computationally easier,
may obscure much of the underlying dynamics
which by hypothesis are what give rise to
structural unemployment. For this reason the
second approach is preferred.'
°
As noted above, certain industries experi-
ence relatively smooth changes in employment
shares over time while others experience much
more volatile changes. While both of these
types of changes can be permanent, intuition
suggests that abrupt permanent changes in
employment share add more to the volume of
unemployment than do smoothly occurring
changes. Thus, the permanent portion of
changes in employment shares that is not
explainable by past experience is the appropri-
ate measure of structural change.
Calculating the difference between the
actual employment share in industry
i
at time
t
and that which would be expected based upon
past behavior is relatively straightforward.
However, separating this measure into its per-
manent and temporary components is a more
complicated endeavor. See Box,
Measuring
structural change.
Assuming that deviations of employment
shares from trend in industry
i
at time
t
can be
accurately decomposed into permanent
changes (AO and temporary changes (Aj) ,
then the measure of permanent structural
change for the aggregate economy at time
t
(AO is simply defined as:
[
E
P
2
[4]
(Azt)
1/2
A
t
Similarly, the measure of temporary change in
employment shares (AD , is defined as:
[
2
1
1/2
(Azt )
[5]
Because the expression in parentheses is
squared, effectively those industries experienc-
ing relatively large permanent changes in em-
ployment shares are weighted more heavily in
the calculation.
The behavior of
AP
and AT from the first
quarter of 1952 through the third quarter of
1981 is examined in Figure 5.
1
' As can be seen,
permanent changes in the distribution of em-
ployment across industries correspond closely
to business cycles, exhibiting quite noticeable
peaks in 1958, 1961, 1970, and 1975, and pos-
sibly in 1980. In contrast, temporary changes
in the employment distribution do not appear
to be significantly correlated with the business
cycle.
A comparison of the measurement of em-
ployment adjustments, ti
-2
, with the constructed
measure of permanent structural change, AP,
yields some interesting insight. The crude
measure of employment adjustment records its
largest value in 1975, leading to the premature
conclusion that structural change was most
Figure 5
Permanent and temporary changes
in the distribution of employment
across industries
1=1
10
Economic Perspectives
Measuring structural change
Let be the /x1 vector of employ-
ment shares at time
t.
Thus
is
is simply
defined as (s
1
„ s
2
„...,
s
11
)
for
t
= 0,. .
T
where (') indicates the transpose and is
the employment share of industry
i
at time
1. The vector of employment shares is as-
sumed to be related to its past and future
values. Specifically, assume that
3
3
3
a
[1
—Z
I
+
E
s
j— t+j j— —j
J=
1
j=1
The left hand side of equation [ii] can be
interpreted as the deviation in current
employment shares from its expected value
based upon past experience. This devi-
ation is seen to be the sum of two compo-
nents: a temporary component, s
1
, and a
permanent component,
=
(1 —
j=
1
[i]
3
3
—Z fi
j
s,_
j
].
3
j=1
where
a,
is some time varying parameter,
the /31s are geometrically declining
weights,
Efl
j
=
1 and
s
t is an additive in-
J=1
dependent and identically distributed
random error term. Thus, the current
vector of employment shares is assumed
to be a two-sided moving average of its
past and future values. Subtracting
E
1
6,,
from both sides of equation [i],
the following results:
3
B .s • =
j =1
j=1
j=1
Equation [ii] can be estimated by
ordinary least squares assuming, a fixed
and specific values for the /31s. The per-
manent component for the th industry is
simply defined as:
3
3
13
j
s
it±i
E
fi
j
s
it
_
j
]
j=i
j=1
where 'A' indicates the estimated value of
the parameter, while the temporary com-
ponent is calculated as the regression resi-
dual:
3
AT
t
sit
E
fl
i
sit„
.7
t[Z
1
—3
i •
s
it
_
j
j=1
j=1
[iv]
pronounced at that time. The more refined
measure of permanent structural change, on
the other hand, clearly indicates that structural
change was far less important a factor in the
1975 recession than it was in the 1970 recession.
Interestingly enough, even the recession that
occurred in 1958 appears to have been associ-
ated with a more pronounced permanent
change in the structure of employment than
was the 1975 recession.
Structural change and the
unemployment rate
The calculation of permanent and
transitory changes in the distribution of em-
ployment across industries is a refinement of the
measure of interindustry employment flows
o
-
i
employed previously. It is constructed so as to
give meaning to the concept of structural
change. If structural change is rapid and ac-
companied by large employment shifts, then
I ederal Reserve Bank of Chicago
11
unemployment is thought to be the by-product
as workers struggle to adapt to the changing
situation.
Analysis of the relation between the com-
puted permanent and transitory variation of
the employment distribution and the unem-
ployment rate may proceed along lines similar
to that presented in Table 1. However, it is
implicitly assumed there that once demo-
graphic changes have been controlled for, all
other unemployment results from cyclical,
structural, or frictional factors where frictional
unemployment is assumed to be some constant
amount. In essence, this assumption denies the
existence of other factors, particularly institu-
tional arrangements, that have an effect upon
the unemployment rate.
Changing institutional conditions are not
cyclical by nature. Nor should they be thought
of as contributing to structural unemployment
because structural unemployment as defined
here is the result of the changing relative de-
mand for different types of labor. These
changing institutional characteristics are most
properly associated with frictional unemploy-
ment. As discussed elsewhere, frictional unem-
ployment arises due to the functioning of a
dynamic labor market where workers are con-
tinuously making decisions as to the proper al-
location of their labor. These decisions are
based upon the parameters of the underlying
institutional framework. Thus, when this
framework changes, it will also have an effect
upon the decisions of the workers to seek work
or quit work, and therefore it will have an ef-
fect upon the frictional rate of unemployment.
Much research has been devoted to ana-
lyzing the effect of unemployment insurance on
job search. Critics argue that the existence of
such unemployment insurance schemes lowers
the costs of job search and therefore encourages
unemployed workers to remain unemployed for
a longer duration than they would have in the
absence of such benefits. Thus, more lenient
benefits tend to increase the unemployment
rate. While this may in fact occur initially, it
is also quite possible that by encouraging peo-
ple to search longer for employment, better job
matches between employees and employers will
result, thereby having a negative long-run ef-
fect on the unemployment rate.
The regression models presented in Table
2 analyze the effect of permanent and
transitory changes in the distribution of em-
ployment on the age-weighted unemployment
rate. As presented previously, other explana-
tory variables include deviations in real Gross
National Product from trend and unantic-
ipated money growth. In light of the preceding
comments on institutional arrangements, an
additional variable is included (SI) which is
social insurance expenditures as a percentage
of Gross National Product.
12
This variable is
assumed to proxy for the costs associated with
unemployment.
Table 2 presents ordinary least square es-
timates from regressions on the civilian age-
weighted unemployment rate over the period
from 1954 through the third quarter of 1981.
Parameter estimates and their associated
standard errors in parentheses' are reported
along with some descriptive statistics. As in the
regressions reported in Table 1, the models of
Table 2 include two lagged dependent vari-
ables. Therefore, the OLS estimates are
asymptotically equivalent to maximum likeli-
hood estimates only if the errors are not
heteroskedastic. The adjusted Box-Pierce sta-
tistic (Q) is reported testing for autocorrelation
of the estimated residuals for a lag length of six
quarters. Judging from the small magnitude
of this statistic, the residuals appear to be
"white noise".
The results indicate that structural
change adversely affects the unemployment
rate while transitory changes in the distribution
of employment across industries have no dis-
cernible effect. As in Table 1, the inclusion of
lagged dependent variables in the regression
model complicates the interpretation of the co-
efficients. This occurs because current struc-
tural change not only affects the current
unemployment rate but also influences the fu-
ture time path of the unemployment rate di-
rectly through a one-quarter lag and indirectly
through the two lagged dependent variables.
Figure 6 reports the results of a simulation
based upon the parameter estimates found in
column (1) of Table 2. The effect of a one
standard deviation temporary increase in AP at
time 1 on the time path of the unemployment
rate is analyzed. By temporary, it is meant that
the disturbance occurs at time 1 after which
AP returns to its previous level. As seen in the
graph, although current structural change ad-
versely affects the unemployment rate both
currently and into the future, the effects damp
quite quickly. A one standard deviation rise in
12
Economic Perspectives
13
16
change
0.48
0.40
10
7
quarters
13
Table 2
Structural change and the
unemployment rate
(1)
(2)
GNP
t
-0.009
-0.009
(0.003)
(0.003)
G
NP
t_1
-0.008 -0.008
(0.003)
(0.003)
GNP
t
_2
-0.002
-0.002
(0.003)
(0.003)
M
t
-7.740
-7.413
(3.330)
(3.444)
Mt-1
3.083
3.293
(3.492)
(3.564)
Mt-2
-0.563
-0.358
(3.780)
(3.848)
ef
94.448
96.450
(14.734)
(16.439)
A
i
tti
-86.213
-88.514
(14.683)
(16.545)
AT
0.537
(35.092)
A
t
L
i
9.103
(36.516)
si
t
3.332
3.158
(1.038)
(1.114)
UR
t
_i
1.185
1.177
(0.078)
(0.082)
UR
t
_2
-0.247
-0.239
(0.078)
(0.081)
C
0.018
-0.072
(0.101)
(0.224)
R2
0.978
0.978
Q
3.30
3.49
lying structure of employment. This is surpris-
ing because it is widely held that structural
change is responsible for creating a large pool
of chronically unemployed workers. However,
the numbers indicate that most of the effect
occurs within two quarters of the disturbance
and long-term effects are minimal. This evi-
dence is at least partially corroborated by sta-
tistics on the distribution of unemployment by
duration.
Table 3 reports for the period 1960 to
1985 the percentage of unemployed workers in
a given year who have been unemployed for
various specified lengths of time. As can be
seen, the vast majority of the unemployed be-
come reemployed (or perhaps leave the labor
force) within six months of losing or leaving a
job. Even in the worst year from unemploy-
ment duration standards, less than a quarter
of the unemployed were unemployed for longer
than twenty-six weeks. In fact, much of the
change in the distribution of unemployment by
duration that has occurred over this time ap-
pears to be related to cyclical factors associated
with a general weakness in the labor market.
Thus, the perception that structural
change leads to a more or less permanent pool
of chronically unemployed workers is not en-
tirely justified. However, this evidence should
not be taken as confirmation that structural
factors have an impact of only limited duration
on the overall performance of the labor market.
It may well be the case that structural change
results in an increased frequency of unemploy-
ment rather than an increased duration so that
AP at time 1 causes the unemployment rate to
rise by approximately one half of a percentage
point that quarter. The following quarter
when
AP
returns to its previous level, the un-
employment rate is still larger than it would
have been by approximately one tenth of a
percentage point. Within four quarters of the
structural change the effect on the unemploy-
ment rate is small, being only one hundredth
of a percentage point and continuing to decline
thereafter. Thus, the long-term effects, i.e.
greater than one year, of structural change on
the unemployment rate are negligible.
The evidence provided in Table 2 and
Figure 6 suggests that the unemployment rate
adjusts quite rapidly to changes in the under-
Federal
Reserve
Bank
of Chicago
Figure 6
Effect of a one standard deviation
increase in structural change on
the unemployment rate
Table 3
Distribution of unemployed
by duration of unemployment,
1960-1985
Year
Less
than
5 weeks
5-14
weeks
15-26
weeks
27
weeks
and
over
1960
45
31
13
12
1961
38
29
15
17
1962
43
29
14
15
1963 43 30
13
14
1964
45
30
13 13
1965
48
29
12
10
1966
55
27 10 8
1967
55
30
9
6
1968
57
29
9 6
1969
58 29
9 5
1970
52
32
10
6
1971
45
32
13
10
1972
46
30
12 12
1973
51
30
11
8
1974
51 31
11
7
1975
37
31
16
15
1976
38 30
14
18
1977 42 30
13 15
1978
46
31
12
10
1979
48
32
12
9
1980
43
32 14
11
1981
42
31
14 14
1982
36
31
16 17
1983
33
27 15 24
1984
39
29
13 19
1985
42
30
12 15
SOURCE:
Economic Report of the President, February 1986,
Table B-33,
a worker who has been displaced by structural
events may become unemployed more often in
the future than those workers who have not
been so affected.1
3
It also appears from Table 3 that social
insurance expenditures are significantly posi-
tively associated with the unemployment rate.
Thus, the evidence supports the hypothesis that
increases in the amount and availability of so-
cial insurance that tend to reduce the opportu-
nity cost of unemployment cause an increase in
the unemployment rate.
Measuring the natural rate
of unemployment
If the natural rate of unemployment is,
as stated earlier, the sum of frictional and
structural unemployment, it is now relatively
straightforward to calculate the natural rate
from the regression results presented previously.
The natural rate is simply calculated as the rate
of unemployment that would result if all cy-
clical variables, namely GNP and M, were set
identically equal to zero over the entire time
period. To implement these computations, it
is necessary to specify initial values for the nat-
ural rate. However, the effect of these initial
values on the calculations decreases rapidly.
As a result, within two years the natural rate
is virtually independent of the assumed initial
values.
Figure 7 presents the actual age-weighted
unemployment rate and the estimate of the
natural rate of unemployment based upon the
parameter estimates found in column (1) of
Table 2. Initial values of the natural rate were
taken to be equal to the actual values of the
unemployment rate for the first and second
quarters of 1954. The figure shows the esti-
mates over the period from 1958 through the
third quarter of 1981 so as to minimize the in-
fluence of this assumption about initial values
on the natural rate.
As seen from the graph, the natural rate
of unemployment has at times been below the
actual unemployment rate and at other times
has been above it. Until late 1966 the natural
rate was consistently below the actual by as
much as two percentage points. From late
1966 through 1973 the reverse occurred al-
though the natural rate never exceeded the ac-
tual by more than one percentage point. The
rise in the natural rate over this time is due
predominantly to the relatively large amount
of structural change that occurred and to a
lesser extent the increase in social insurance
expenditures as a percentage of GNP. From
1974 through 1977 the actual rate again ex-
ceeded the natural rate while for the brief pe-
riod from 1978 to 1981 the opposite was true.
Not only has the relation between the ac-
tual and natural rates of unemployment
changed over time, but the estimate of the
natural rate has varied widely from a high of
7.01 percent in the third quarter of 1981 to a
low of 3.48 percent in the first quarter of 1966.
This variability of the natural rate makes ap-
propriate policy-making difficult.
As suggested in the introduction, the dif-
ference between the natural rate of unemploy-
ment and the actual rate of unemployment is
directly related to movements in the inflation
rate. If the natural rate exceeds the actual
rate, then labor market conditions are tight
14
Econo
171
ic
Perspectives
8
6
4
1,81t
'77
3
71
Figure 7
The natural and fixed-weight
unemployment rates
percent
9
Figure 8
Inflation and the natural rate
of employment
and inflation occurs. Conversely, if the actual
rate exceeds the natural rate, then labor mar-
ket conditions are slack and lower inflation or
even possibly deflation results. Thus, the in-
flation rate should be positively correlated with
the calculated difference. This indeed seems to
be the case. The estimated correlation coeffi-
cient between the inflation rate and the differ-
ence between the natural and actual rates of
unemployment is computed to be 0.46, indi-
cating that the two do vary directly. In addi-
tion, there is no apparent linear relation
between the inflation rate and the actual un-
employment rate as the calculated correlation
coefficient is a mere -0.01. Although these cal-
culations are somewhat crude, they indicate
that inflation does not depend upon the actual
level of unemployment but rather the actual
rate relative to the natural rate.
Figure 8 displays both the difference be-
tween the natural and actual rates and the an-
nual inflation rate based upon quarterly data.
The inflation rate from 1958 through 1966
fluctuates around two percent per year with no
noticeable upward trend. During this time the
actual unemployment rate was above the nat-
ural unemployment rate, implying that labor
market conditions were somewhat slack. From
1967 to 1973 labor market conditions appear
to be tighter as the natural rate rose above the
actual. Inflation appears to be trending up-
wards during the same time period. Finally,
the two drops in the difference between the
natural and actual rates of unemployment oc-
curring in 1975 and again in 1980 appear to
coincide with rapid declines in the inflation
rate.
While the two series are clearly positively
related, a great deal of the variation in the in-
flation rate is unexplainable by changes in this
measure of labor market tightness. If the esti-
mates of the natural rate of unemployment are
indeed correct, then a more adequate under-
standing of inflation requires incorporating
other elements of the economy, such as mone-
tary policy, into the analysis.
Conclusions
The historically high unemployment rates
of recent decades are attributable in large part
to a combination of two factors: rapid and
pronounced structural change and low aggre-
gate demand. Although demographic changes
in the composition of the labor force have
tended to adversely affect the unemployment
rate, the actual impact has been quite modest.
The unemployment of the 1970s is at-
tributable in large part to shifts in the distri-
bution of employment across industries brought
on by some sort of structural change. Unfor-
tunately, the measure of structural change de-
veloped can be computed only with a four-year
lag, thereby making policy decisions based
upon such dated calculations inadvisable.
Nevertheless, the need for policymakers to have
some knowledge of the current magnitude of
structural change is quite real.
The evidence on interindustry employ-
ment flows suggests that structural change has
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
15
not been as large a determinant of unemploy-
ment in the 1980s as it was in the 1970s. Thus,
the double-digit unemployment of recent years
is more closely associated with cyclical rather
than structural or frictional factors.
Extrapolation of data used in the compu-
tation of Figure 7 suggests that the current
natural rate of unemployment is approximately
6 percent. Given the actual unemployment
rate of 7.07 for the first quarter of 1986, it ap-
pears that policymakers need not be unduly
concerned with inflation at this time.
1
The
discussion here is based to a large extent on
Ronald G. Ehrenberg's and Robert S. Smith's book
entitled
Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public
Policy,
2nd edition, published by Scott, Foresman
and Company, 1985.
2
Real wages may not readily respond to decreases
in aggregate demand because of long-term labor
contracts which specify nominal wages, minimum
wage legislation, and risk aversion on the part of
workers who prefer fixed real wages and more var-
iable employment.
3
The unemployment rates have been constructed
as in equation [1] so as to guarantee that the sum
of the y
11
's equals one.
4
The age categories investigated were
16-to-19-year-olds, 20-to-24-year-olds, and those
25-years-of-age or older.
5
Other traditional industries include construction,
mining, transportation and public utilities.
Service-related industries refer to wholesale and
retail trades, finance, insurance, and real estate.
6
This phenomenon was originally documented by
Wesley C. Mitchell in
Business Cycles and Their
Causes,
(Berkeley, CA: University of California
Press, 1941).
7
The industry categories examined include gov-
ernment, construction, mining, durable manufac-
turing, nondurable manufacturing, transportation
and public utilities, services, wholesale trades, retail
trades, and finance, insurance, and real estate.
8
The dependent variable in the analysis is the
fixed-weight unemployment rate adjusting for the
effects of the changing age composition of the labor
force. Similar calculations were also performed on
the unadjusted unemployment rate but provide lit-
tle additional insight.
In the absence of serially correlated errors, ordi-
nary least squares is equivalent to maximum likeli-
hood estimation for large sample sizes. The
adjusted Box-Pierce statistic (Q) is reported testing
for serial correlation of the residuals through a lag
length of six quarters. In all three regressions the
hypothesis that the estimated residual is not serially
correlated can be accepted at the five percent sig-
nificance level.
The measurement of permanent change in the
distribution of employment across industries dis-
cussed below is found in George R. Neumann and
Robert
H.
Topel, "Employment Risk, Sectoral
Shifts, and the Geographical Distribution of Un-
employment," forthcoming
Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics.
11
Calculations are based upon the same ten indus-
tries as those used in computing r
2
. The measures
have been compiled assuming J = 16, creating a
four-year lag in the estimate. As a result, values
of
AP
and AT can be estimated only through the
third quarter of 1981. The
fi
b
's
are assumed to be
geometrically declining weights that sum to unity
over 16 quarters. Therefore, /i
i
=
CqJ
where
C=
(1 —
q)l[q(1 —
q")]. The results reported here
are based upon the assumption that
q =
0.9.
However, in practice the actual weighting scheme
used makes little difference in the final results. [See
box for a discussion of the estimation.]
12
Social insurance expenditures is available annu-
ally from the Social Security Administration's
Social
Security Bulletin: Annual Statistical Supplement.
Quarterly data were calculated by linear interpo-
lation.
13
Some limited evidence to this effect is found in
Robert E. Hall's article, "Why Is the Unemploy-
ment Rate So High at Full Employment?" in
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
vol. 3: 1970, pp.
369-396.
16
Economic Perspectives
Bibliography
Barro, Robert J., "Unanticipated Money, Output,
and the Price Level in the United States,"
Journal of Political Economy,
August 1978,
86(4), pp. 549-80.
Hall, Robert R., "Why Is The Unemployment
Rate So High at Full Employment?,"
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
1970(3),
pp. 369-410.
Lilien, David. "Sectoral Shifts and Sectoral Unem-
ployment,"
Journal of Political Economy,
Au-
gust 1982, 90(4), pp. 777-93.
Mitchell, Wesley C.,
Business Cycles and Their
Causes,
(Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press, 1941).
Neumann, George R. and Robert H. Topel, "Em-
ployment Risk, Sectoral Shifts, and the Ge-
ographical Distribution of Unemployment,"
forthcoming
Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
17