THE ECONOMIC BENEFITS
OF U.S. TRADE
May 2015
2
Table of Contents
Ten Facts about U.S. Trade ....................................................................................................................... 3
I. Introduction .......................................................................................................................................... 5
II. The Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Integration .............................................................................. 7
Classic Gains from Trade .............................................................................................................. 7
Enhanced Productivity ........................................................................................................... 7
More Innovative Activity ..................................................................................................... 11
Higher Living Standards ....................................................................................................... 12
Labor Market Implications of Trade and Trade Agreements ................................................ 14
Higher Wages ........................................................................................................................ 14
Development Effects of Trade ................................................................................................... 22
Increased Economic Growth ............................................................................................... 22
Better Working Conditions .................................................................................................. 24
Stronger Environmental Protection ................................................................................... 26
Broader Inclusion and Participation ................................................................................... 29
III. Sector-Specific Trends in U.S. Trade ............................................................................................... 33
The Rise of Services Trade.......................................................................................................... 35
Manufacturing Rebound ............................................................................................................ 38
Robust Agricultural Trade .......................................................................................................... 40
IV. Current Trade Negotiations .............................................................................................................. 43
Trans-Pacific Partnership............................................................................................................ 45
Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership ................................................................... 46
V. Conclusion ........................................................................................................................................... 47
References ................................................................................................................................................. 48
3
Ten Facts about U.S. Trade
President Obama’s top priority is to make sure the United States builds on its economic
momentum by continuing to grow businesses, create jobs, and expand the middle class. That is
why the President is committed to free and fair trade agreements that level the playing field and
benefit American businesses and workers. This report presents original empirical evidence,
alongside a summary of the extensive economic literature, on a broad range of effects of
enhanced U.S. trade and U.S. free trade agreements (FTAs).
1
Highlights from this report include:
1. U.S. businesses must overcome an average tariff hurdle of 6.8 percent, in addition to
numerous non-tariff barriers (NTBs), to serve the roughly 95 percent of the world’s
customers outside our borders. The United States is already one of the most open markets
in the world, meaning that the main impact of new trade agreements would be to decrease
foreign barriers to U.S. exports. In 2014, almost 70 percent of U.S. imports crossed our
borders duty-free, but many of our trading partners maintain higher tariffs that create steep
barriers to U.S. exports.
2. Exporters pay higher wages, and the average industry’s export growth over the past twenty
years translated into $1,300 higher annual earnings for the typical employee. Studies of U.S.
manufacturing industries document that, on average, export-intensive industries pay workers
up to 18 percent more than non-export-intensive industries. Controlling for industry,
location, and worker characteristics, CEA finds that the average industry’s increase in exports
in the 1990s and 2000s translated into an additional $1,300 in annual earnings for the typical
middle-class worker.
3. Middle-class Americans gain more than a quarter of their purchasing power from trade.
Trade allows U.S. consumers to buy a wider variety of goods at lower prices, raising real wages
and helping families purchase more with their current incomes. This is especially important
for middle-class consumers who spend a larger share of their disposable income on heavily-
traded food and clothing items. Compared to a world with no trade, median-income
consumers gain an estimated 29 percent of their purchasing power from trade.
4. Over the past twenty years, the average industry’s increase in exports translated into 8
percent higher labor productivity, or almost a quarter of the total productivity increase over
that time. About half of all U.S. imports are inputs that businesses use to produce final goods,
which lowers firms’ production costs by making a greater variety of inputs available at lower
prices. Additionally, economic research shows that trade increases productivity for
businesses and the economy as a whole.
5. When countries make trade deals with China, outsourcing of American jobs increases, while
U.S. trade agreements do not change the rate of U.S. investment abroad. Trade agreements
1
This report complements work already published in Chapter 7 of the Council of Economic Advisers’ (CEA) 2015
Economic Report of the President.
4
with China offer countries preferential access to the vast Chinese market while accepting low
labor and environmental standards. U.S. FTAs, on the other hand, raise standards across the
board and help U.S. businesses export to foreign markets while still producing goods here.
U.S. foreign direct investment (FDI) in FTA partner countries shows little to no change after
completion of a trade agreement. However, China’s completion of a trade agreement
increases U.S. FDI in China’s FTA partners.
6. Trade raises labor standards and incomes abroad, helping developing countries lift people
out of poverty and expanding markets for U.S. exports. Research suggests that trade has
helped decrease poverty by raising wages around the world and also finds that expanding
U.S. market access promotes higher-quality employment in less-developed countries as
workers shift from informal to formal employment. Enforceable labor standards, which form
a central part of trade agreements the United States is currently negotiating, have also
complemented trade’s direct effects.
7. For every 1 percent increase in income as a result of trade liberalization, pollution
concentrations fall by 1 percent. This happens because the adoption of clean technologies
spread through trade more than offsets emissions resulting from increased transportation or
production. Current trade agreements amplify these effects: the Administration includes
environmental commitments as a core part of its values-driven trade approach, including
commitments to protect oceans, combat wildlife trafficking, and eliminate illegal logging.
8. Trade helps lower the gender wage gap, with a 10 percentage point decrease in tariffs
leading to a 1 percentage point drop in the wage gap. CEA studied the relationship between
tariffs and the gender wage gap, finding that industries with larger tariff declines saw greater
reductions in the wage gap. Trade also decreases discrimination based on race and
immigration status and is correlated with better human-rights conditions.
9. The United States has a $43 billion surplus in agricultural trade and is a worldwide leader
in agriculture, employing almost 1.5 million American workers. In 2014, one-half of the
wheat, rice, and soybeans produced in the United States was exported, along with over two-
thirds of almonds and walnuts and four-fifths of cotton and pistachios. The U.S. Department
of Agriculture (USDA) estimates that every $1 in agricultural exports stimulates another $1.22
in related business activity, so that agricultural exports increased total economic output by
almost $350 billion in 2014.
10. The United States is the global leader in services exports. Over the past 34 years, real U.S.
services exports have grown more than seven-fold, particularly in areas like insurance and
financial services. As a result, knocking down barriers to services trade is especially important
for the American workforce. Compared to the average across 40 other countries, including
most advanced economies and large emerging markets, the United States has lower trade
barriers in 14 out of 18 different service sectors. By one estimate, if U.S. services reached the
same export potential as manufactured goods, total U.S. exports could increase by as much
as $800 billion.
5
I. Introduction
The world’s economies are more interconnected than ever before. Since the middle of the last
century, declining policy barriers, transportation costs, and communication costs have driven a
swift rise in world trade and foreign investment, far outpacing the growth in world output. Even
so, the potential economic gains from trade for the United States are far from exhausted. U.S.
businesses must overcome an average tariff hurdle near 6.8 percent and countless non-tariff
measures to serve the roughly three-quarters of world purchasing power and more than 95
percent of world population that resides outside America's borders.
Expanding trade allows production inputs such as labor and capital to be used more efficiently,
which raises overall productivity. U.S. businesses that grow in response to increased market
access abroad support additional job opportunities. These firms are more productive and rely
more on capital and skilled workers, on average, than similar non-exporting firms. Partly because
of this, the wages paid by exporting firms tend to be higher than wages paid by non-exporters in
the same industry. In particular, evidence for the United States suggests that, in manufacturing,
average wages in exporting firms and industries are up to 18 percent higher than average wages
in non-exporting firms and industries.
In addition, international trade helps U.S. households’ budgets go further. Because our trading
partners also specialize in the goods and services for which they are relatively more productive,
the prices of those goods and services in the United States are lower than if we could only
consume what we produce. Trade also offers a much greater diversity of consumption
opportunities, from year-round fresh fruit to affordable clothing. In fact, research estimates that
the variety of imported goods increased approximately three-fold between 1972 and 2001. This
increase in variety provides U.S. consumers with value equivalent to 2.6 percent of gross
domestic product (GDP). According to other estimates, the reduction in U.S. tariffs since World
War II contributed an additional 7.3 percent to U.S. GDP, or approximately $1.3 trillion in 2014.
Distributed equally, that translates into an additional over $10,000 in income per American
household.
By increasing global production and consumption opportunities, international trade can promote
world economic growth and development. Trade among nations offers a mechanism to reduce
global poverty, which may decrease child labor and pull developing-country workers into jobs
with improved working conditions. Trade can also be a force toward the empowerment of
traditionally marginalized groups; for example, some empirical evidence suggests that decreased
discrimination against women is related to the effects of global competition brought about by
trade. Trade also facilitates the spread of new green technologies throughout the world, which
decreases emissions and improves air and water quality.
Because the process of globalization shifts resources within national economies, however, it can
also create challenges in areas like income inequality. For this reason, it is critical that
globalization is managedin terms of both the types of trade agreements the United States
enters into and the domestic policies that are in placein a way that ensures that more
6
Americans can take advantage of the opportunities afforded by trade, while being better able to
meet any challenges trade creates. Therefore, President Obama’s values-driven trade policy
seeks to do what is best for U.S. businesses and workers by enforcing international agreements
that improve labor and environmental standards around the world, combat corruption, and
strengthen the rule of law abroad. Encouraging such trade agreements maximizes globalization’s
benefits while minimizing globalization’s side effects. For example, new U.S. trade agreements
promote and enforce the rights of workers abroad, “leveling up” rather than “leveling down” and
risking workers’ rights in the United States. The Administration’s domestic policies, such as skills
training, infrastructure investment, and business tax reform, allow workers and firms to take
better advantage of the opportunities trade offers. At the same time, policies like Trade
Adjustment Assistance and the Affordable Care Act help protect workers from some of the
challenges associated with globalization.
The rest of this report is structured as follows. In Section II, we highlight the main economic
benefits of U.S. trade integration, starting with a review of the classic gains from trade, such as
higher productivity, faster innovation, lower prices, and more varieties. Next, we survey research
showing how trade supports jobs in larger, more productive, and higher-paying exporting firms
and comment on the role of U.S. FTAs in the outsourcing of jobs. The section ends with a
discussion of often overlooked development effects of expanding trade relations. Section III
presents a brief analysis of sector-specific trends in U.S. trade, highlighting separately
manufacturing, agriculture, and services. Section IV focuses on current trade negotiations with
countries in the Asia-Pacific (Trans-Pacific Partnership, TPP) and the European Union
(Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership, T-TIP), and section V concludes.
7
II. The Economic Effects of U.S. Trade Integration
The process of globalization offers many new economic opportunities, but it also has created
challenges. Globalization is a result of both worldwide economic, social, and technological trends,
as well as specific policy changes. Analyzing globalization’s general impact is different from
analyzing any particular trade agreement. Understanding the impact of any particular agreement
requires both historical context, as well as an analysis of the relative tariffs of trading partners,
NTBs, and the relevant standards (for instance, on labor, environment, and intellectual property).
Classic Gains from Trade
Nevertheless, historical experience does underscore the potentially large gains from trade. In the
past half-century, as trade barriers around the world have diminished, these gains have
multiplied and are increasingly shared across different countries and different industries. Among
these classic gains from trade are enhanced productivity, increased innovative activity, and lower
prices on and greater variety of goods and services for consumers and producers.
Enhanced Productivity
Defined as the amount of output that can be generated with a given level of inputs, total factor
productivity (TFP) growth is historically associated with increasing real wages. Productivity
growth is necessary for sustained faster income growth of U.S. workers and profoundly important
for the living standards of middle-class Americans, in particular. Specifically, one of the major
factors in disappointing middle-class income growth since the 1970s has been the slowdown in
productivity growth that started around 1973. In fact, if productivity had continued growing at
the same rate as it did between 1948 and 1973that is to say, at 1.9 percent per yearand
inequality followed its actual path, then Americans’ annual incomes in 2013 would have been 58
percent higher, a fraction equivalent to roughly $30,000 per household.
There is a large body of economic research on the relationship between international trade and
productivity growth, and its conclusions are generally positive for trade. For example, a recent
review by De Loecker and Goldberg (2014) concludes that “there is one robust finding that
emerges from this literature: globalization improves industry performance.” However, this
literature has not reached a consensus on why trade improves productivity. Long-established
theories of international trade suggest that trade liberalization will improve a nation’s economic
productivity through several different channels.
Production Reallocation
First, trade can improve economy-wide productivity by allowing each country to focus on its
comparative advantage. This benefit follows from the classic theory of trade gains first
expounded by economist David Ricardo in 1817. Productivity gains can also occur within an
industry if there is some heterogeneity between firms in that industry (Melitz 2003), as labor and
resources shift in response to lower trade costs to the most efficient firmsthose best able to
take advantage of the opportunity to export. Several studies find evidence of this phenomenon
in U.S. manufacturing. For example, one study compares high- and low-productivity plants during
a time of falling tariffs and transportation costs and finds that industry productivity rises when
8
trade costs fall (Bernard et al. 2006). Additionally, trade may improve the productivity of specific
firms in an industry or even a single factory. If increased trade liberalization creates more demand
from overseas for certain products, firms may be induced to reallocate resources toward core
products. Bernard et al. (2011) find evidence to this effect.
Increased Market Size
Beyond the productivity gains from reallocation, additional gains arise when firms’ export
markets expand as the foreign trade barriers they face fall. If these firms can become more
efficient as they grow (a phenomenon known as economies of scale), their productivity will rise.
Lileeva and Trefler (2010) find evidence that Canadian firms that received preferential access to
the huge U.S. market under the terms of the 1989 Canada-U.S. FTA improved labor productivity
by investing in productivity-enhancing activities. Bustos (2011) finds similar evidence from
Argentina, which entered into a trade agreement with Brazil, Paraguay, and Uruguay in 1991.
Across these studies, the common mechanism is that exporting induces investments in
technology.
Learning-by-Exporting
Since the early 1990s, empirical research on trade has increasingly focused on firm-level data,
and several recent studies have found evidence of a causal link from trade to increased
productivity. Export activity offers firms opportunities to learn about foreign marketsperhaps
even gaining technical expertise from foreign buyersleading to increased productivity (De
Loecker 2013). Productivity gains through exporting may also occur through increased
competition from foreign producers. This “learning-by-exporting” theory has support in a
literature spanning many countries and time periods. For example, De Loecker (2007) finds
evidence of learning by exporting for Slovenia and Van Biesebroeck (2005) finds support in sub-
Saharan Africa. A recent paper by Atkin, Khandelwal, and Osman (2014) experimentally
manipulates access to trade so as to simulate a randomized trial, and finds strong evidence that
Egyptian rug manufacturers (who randomly received an opportunity to export) became more
productive as a consequence of foreign trading opportunities.
While these findings may or may not generalize to more technologically advanced U.S. exporters,
they provide important evidence of a causal link between trade and productivity, suggesting that
the productivity improvements associated with trade do not necessarily only come through
domestic resource reallocation. Using data from the U.S. Census Bureau’s Foreign Trade Statistics
in combination with data from the National Bureau of Economic Research’s (NBER)
Manufacturing Industry Database (Becker, Gray, and Marvakov 2013) for the years 1989 to 2009,
CEA’s analysis confirms findings in the literature on the productivity-enhancing effects of
international trade. Table 1 reports coefficient estimates for two different specifications relating
trade to the level of labor productivity, defined as value-added per employee. Across the 377 6-
digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) industries, CEA documents the
positive association of international trade and labor productivity.
9
Relying on cross-industry and over-time variation in trade, our estimation includes industry fixed
effects to control for time-invariant differences across industries, which may affect productivity
levels, as well as year fixed effects to account for common cyclical variation, including in inflation.
The estimation also controls for industry size and the level of importing, where relevant. Though
the estimate implies that tariff reductions are associated with decreases in labor productivity,
this measured effect is insignificantly different from zero. The estimates in the second column,
however, point to a statistically and economically significant relationship. Industries with larger
increases in exports report larger increases in labor productivity. A 10 percent increase in an
industry’s exports is associated with a 0.2 percent increase in the industry’s labor productivity.
Over the two decades between 1989 and 2009, based on the average industry’s increase in
exports, these estimates imply approximately an additional 8 percent labor productivity boost as
compared to what would have happened with no change in international trade. Since average
labor productivity in the United States increased by about 35 percent over these two decades,
these estimates imply that international trade may have been responsible for about one quarter
of total productivity growth over the 1990s and 2000s.
The literature also suggests that many productivity improvements associated with exporting are
due to increased investments in technology. We provide some evidence for this hypothesis in
Table 2, which documents that industries with larger increases in exports are also those industries
with the largest increases in capital investment. Specifically, a 10 percent increase in exports is
associated with about a 0.6 percent increase in investment. Therefore, the average industry
invested about 22 percent more over the 1990s and 2000s, than would have been the case in a
world with no change in exports.
Tariff
0.060
(0.047)
Log Exports
0.022*
(0.013)
Indus try Fi xed Effects YES YES
Yea r Fixed Effects YES YES
Control for Imports NO YES
Control for Indus try Size YES YES
Observa tions 7,871 7,961
Log Labor Producti vity
Table 1: Trade and Labor Productivity
Note: Labor productivity is defined as value added per employee. Tariffs are the simple average of applied rates. Industry size is
defined as the inflation-adjusted value of total shipments by U.S. firms. Robust standard errors, clustered at the industry level, are in
parentheses. *** denotes significance at the 1-percent level, ** denotes significance at the 5-percent level, and * denotes significance
at the 10-percent level. The panel dataset comprises over 370 industries over the 1989-2009 period. Industries are defined according
to NAICS and are disaggregated to the six-digit level.
Source: Data on value added, employment, total shipments, and industry-specific price indices are from the NBER Manufacturing
Industry Database. Data on tariff rates are from the World Integrated Trade Solution database maintained by the United Nations
Statistical Division. Data on imports and exports by industry from 1989-2006 are from the U.C. Davis Center for International Data.
Data on imports and exports by industry from 2007-2009 are from the Foreign Trade Division of the U.S. Census Bureau.
10
Table 3 takes the analysis one step further to ask whether trade liberalization via decreases in
tariffs increases the rate of productivity growth. Industries that faced larger tariff declines over
the 1990s and 2000s experienced larger increases in both labor productivity growth and TFP
growth. A 10 percentage point decrease in tariffs corresponds to about a 0.4 percentage point
increase in labor productivity growth and about a half percentage point increase in TFP growth
over the two decades. In an era of relatively low productivity growth, these are large changes.
In summary, some studies conclude that trade leads to increased industry-wide productivity
through a reallocation of market share towards more productive firms (Melitz 2003; Bernard and
Log Investment
Log Exports
0.063*
(0.034)
Indus try Fixed Effects YES
Year Fixed Effects YES
Control for Imports YES
Control for Industry Size YES
Observa ti ons 7,961
Table 2: Trade and Investment
Source: Data on investment, total shipments, and industry-specific price indices are
from the NBER M anufacturing Industry Database. Data on imports and exports by
industry from 1989-2006 are from the U.C. Davis Center for International Data. Data on
imports and exports by industry from 2007-2009 are from the Foreign Trade Division of
the U.S. Census Bureau.
Note: Investment is deflated using industry-specific price deflators. Industry size is
defined as the inflation-adjusted value of total shipments by U.S. firms. Robust
standard errors, clustered at the industry level, are in parentheses. *** denotes
significance at the 1-percent level, ** denotes significance at the 5-percent level, and *
denotes significance at the 10-percent level. The panel dataset comprises over 370
industries over the 1989-2009 period. Industries are defined according to NAICS and are
disaggregated to the six-digit level.
Labor Productivi ty Growth TFP Growth
Tariff
-0.041*** -0.048***
(0.007) (0.006)
Indus try Fi xed Effects YES YES
Yea r Fixed Effects YES YES
Control for Indus try Size YES YES
Observa tions 7,867 7,867
Table 3: Trade and Productivity Growth
Note: Labor productivity is defined as value added per employee. TFP is defined as in Becker et al. (2013). Labor productivity growth
and TFP growth are defined as the one-year growth rate. Tariffs are the simple average of applied rates. Industry size is defined as
the inflation-adjusted value of total shipments by U.S. firms. Robust standard errors, clustered at the industry level, are in
parentheses. *** denotes significance at the 1-percent level, ** denotes significance at the 5-percent level, and * denotes significance
at the 10-percent level. The panel dataset comprises over 370 industries over the 1989-2009 period. Industries are defined according
to NAICS and are disaggregated to the six-digit level.
Source: Data on value added, employment, TFP growth, total shipments, and industry-specific price indices are from the NBER
Manufacturing Industry Database. Data on tariff rates are from the World Integrated Trade Solution database maintained by the
United Nations Statistical Division.
11
Jensen 1999; 2004a; 2004b). In other words, the selection of the most productive firms into
international markets means that productivity may cause trade. Other studies argue that the
causality goes in the opposite direction, with global trade driving increases in productivity (for
example, Lileeva and Trefler 2010 and Bloom, Draca, and Van Reenen 2011). It is difficult to
distinguish between these two mechanisms empirically, since both suggest a positive relationship
between trade and productivity. And in practice, both stories could be correct: trade may cause
productivity, at the same time as productivity causes trade.
More Innovative Activity
Most people associate the term “innovation” with new tools and technologies that improve their
daily lives. This makes sense; major innovations like the automobile or computer have a visible
impact on living standards. Economists, on the other hand, tend to focus on aggregate
innovation, as measured by TFP, as we touched on in the previous section. However, a growing
body of work also considers the impact of trade on innovative activities, such as research and
development (R&D) spending and patenting. Because there are several different mechanisms
that could produce this effect, it is helpful to divide the relevant theoretical channels into two
broad groups: (1) trade stimulates innovation directly, and (2) trade alters the incentives to
innovate.
Innovation Production Function
Both exporters and importers are frequently exposed to new ideas and novel tools, materials, or
techniques that make them more productive. Some of the learning that results is simply copying.
For example, many multinational companies have systems and standards to promote the
diffusion of “best practices” within their global supply chains (MacDuffie and Helper 1997 and
Distelhorst, Hainmueller, and Locke 2014). Learning also occurs when a firm adapts novel ideas
to suit its own operating environment, leading to both new goods and greater productivity. For
example, many American manufacturers and businesses in other industries have adopted aspects
of the “lean” production system, which was originally developed in Japan, and realized
substantial productivity benefits by tailoring the underlying ideas to meet their own needs (Teich
and Faddoul 2013).
Many of the new ideas that diffuse through trade are embodied in intermediate inputs. In fact,
roughly half of all U.S. imports are inputs into the production of final goods. Increases in the
quality and variety of these inputs can reduce domestic firms’ production costs, thereby inducing
American importers to expand production and employment. For example, Romer (1994) shows
that a country’s gains from international trade increase substantially when the benefits of
cheaper and more varied imported production inputs are taken into account.
Trade can also increase innovative productivity by allowing innovators to specialize. Greater
specialization can increase the amount of knowledge produced per unit of R&D investment if
companies in different countries focus on innovating in the areas where they have a comparative
advantage. For example, if engineers at one firm focus on improving memory chips, and
engineers at another firm focus on improving microprocessors, the R&D productivity of each firm
may be higher, leading to better and cheaper computers than if each company had to improve
12
both components simultaneously. Branstetter, Fisman, and Foley (2006) show that strengthening
foreign intellectual property protection leads to more outward licensing from the United States,
where U.S. companies allow other companies to use their ideas, products, or processes in
exchange for royalty payments. Specifically, the authors find that royalty payments from foreign
affiliates to U.S. parent companies increase by 16.6 percent on average following a reform that
strengthens intellectual property rights in the affiliates’ home country. This finding highlights the
role of NTBs for shaping trade in ideas, particularly if one country specializes in the “R” and the
other in the “D.”
2
The Incentives to Innovate
International trade allows companies to access a larger market, which yields more profit for a
given level of innovation, and therefore raises the incentive to innovate. For example, the global
reach of the “App Stores” managed by Apple and Google contributes to the large number of
software developers who populate those distribution platforms. Aw, Roberts, and Xu (2008) find
that firms with experience in foreign markets have a greater probability of R&D investment,
consistent with the idea that accessing larger foreign markets translates into higher expected
returns to R&D.
Even holding market size constant, increased trade can promote innovation by strengthening
competition. More than fifty years ago, Arrow (1962) pointed out that a monopolist may have
relatively weak incentives to innovate because its innovations do not allow it to “steal” business
from competitors. A similar idea appears in more recent Schumpeterian models of innovation
and economic growth (Aghion et al. 2005), where competition can promote growth by increasing
the expected payoffs of successful innovation. By bringing companies into a worldwide
marketplace, trade greatly increases the incentive for a firm to innovate in order to win business
from its competitors (Bloom, Draca, and van Reenen 2011), reinforcing the market-size effects
discussed above. However, Schumpeterian models also suggest that too much competition can
reduce innovation, because firms will not wish to invest in R&D if their discoveries are easily
copied and the resulting profits immediately dissipated.
Higher Living Standards
Perhaps the most broadly shared benefit of increased trade is lower prices for consumers and
producers in the domestic market. By allowing our trading partners to produce the goods in
which they are relatively more efficient, the United States can import at lower prices than would
prevail if we were to use our scarce resources to produce the goods ourselves. This “specialize in
what you do best, trade for the rest” philosophy makes everyday goods and services more
affordable and enhances the real earning power of American workers and families current
incomes.
Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2014) note that lower-income consumers spend a larger share of
their disposable income on heavily-traded food and clothing items, while higher-income
consumers devote a relatively larger share to spending on services, which can be harder or
2
For more analysis of trade in ideas, please see Box 7-1 in CEA (2015a).
13
impossible to trade. This implies that international trade is relatively more beneficial to middle-
class consumers. Specifically, as is illustrated in Figure 1, the authors estimate that U.S.
consumers at the 10
th
percentile of the income distribution would lose more than half of their
purchasing power if the United States shut out all international trade, owing to higher prices.
Median-income consumers would still lose more than a quarter of their purchasing power, as
compared to only a 3 percent gain in purchasing power for Americans at the 90
th
percentile of
the income distribution. Although these estimates are based on an extreme counterfactual, the
numbers remind us of the potential for new trade agreements to reduce prices in the United
States and raise consumers’ purchasing power, particularly for middle-class consumers.
Another underappreciated benefit of trade liberalization is increased variety for domestic
consumers and producers. With new importers come new products. This expanded selection
increases the welfare of consumers who appreciate having more choice. Broda and Weinstein
(2006) examine historical trade statistics and determine that the variety of imported goods
increased approximately three-fold between 1972 and 2001. Conventional import price indices
have trouble incorporating the value of increased choice, so this finding suggests that import
prices have effectively fallen even further than the conventional import price index would
suggest. The researchers estimate that this increased variety has provided U.S. consumers with
value equivalent to 2.6 percent of GDP, or approximately $450 billion in 2014. Mostashari (2010)
updates the calculations in Broda and Weinstein (2006) and reports that the number of varieties
of goods imported into the United States increased 33 percent between 1989 and 2007.
In addition, recent estimates suggest that over one-half of all U.S. imports are intermediate
inputs into the production process. The greater variety of imports available at lower prices
reduces firms’ production costs, thereby helping American businesses to expand production and
employment and increase the wages they can afford to pay. Since World War II, reductions in
U.S. tariffs are estimated to have contributed an additional 7.3 percent to U.S. GDP (Bradford,
Grieco, and Hufbauer 2005).
62
29
3
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
10th 50th 90th
Figure 1: Gains from Trade Across the Income Distribution
Percent of Purchasing Power Gained from Trade
Income Percentiles
Aggregate
Gains
Source: Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (2014).
14
Labor Market Implications of Trade and Trade Agreements
Trade also has notable impacts on labor markets, many of them a direct result of the classic gains
from trade in terms of increased productivity and innovation. U.S. businesses that expand in
response to the increased foreign market access due to U.S. trade agreements support additional
jobs. The importance of such export-led job growth for the Nation’s income is reinforced by the
fact that wages in export-intensive manufacturing industries tend to be higher than wages in non-
export-intensive manufacturing industries. Of course, while the aggregate benefits of trade may
be large, they may also be unevenly distributed.
3
Trade, therefore, can also have adverse effects
for some workers. Domestic policies the Administration supports, such as investment in
infrastructure, worker training, and education, can help our labor force take advantage of the
considerable opportunities that trade opens up. For displaced workers and their families,
effective policies can help smooth the adjustment into new, potentially higher-paying jobs.
Higher Wages
Expanding U.S. market access abroad has important implications for the workforce at home. A
very long literature spanning decades and many different countries highlights that exporting
firms are systematically different from non-exporting firms even within the same industrial
category. Bernard and Jensen (1995) were the first to document this fact for the United States.
They note that exporting plants are larger in terms of employment, more productive in terms of
value added per worker, more strongly capital-intensive, and pay higher wages. These
differences persist even within detailed industrial categories, and controlling for firms’ regional
locations.
Figure 2 offers descriptive evidence relying on data from the U.S. Census Bureau’s Foreign Trade
Statistics matched to the NBER’s Manufacturing Industry Database. Export-intensive industries
are defined as those industries with above-average values of exports as a fraction of total
shipments (the export share) in 1989, and non-export-intensive industries are those industries
with below-average values of the export share in 1989.
4
For ease of illustration, in order to report
the various characteristics in comparable units, the Figure reports the industry’s characteristic as
a ratio to the average industry’s characteristic, calculated as described in the Figure note. On
average over the 1989 to 2009 period of data availability, relative to non-export-intensive
industries, export-intensive industries report 51 percent higher TFP growth, 17 percent higher
average wages (total wage bill per worker), 10 percent higher levels of labor productivity (total
shipments per worker), 17 percent higher value added per worker, and 31 percent higher capital
intensity (total real capital stock per worker), consistent with the findings in the academic
research.
3
For an examination of the relationship between trade and income inequality, refer to Chapter 7 of CEA (2015a). In
addition, Harrison, McLaren, and McMillan (2011) provide a summary of the large literature on the links between
globalization and inequality.
4
The average export share across the 377 6-digit NAICS industries was 12.7 percent in 1989.
15
Exporter Wage Premium
That exporters pay higher wages than similar non-exporters is a well-established feature of the
data across many countries and over decades (see Table 1 in Schank, Schnabel, and Wagner
2004). For the United States, estimates for the exporter wage premium (the amount by which
exporting industries and firms pay higher wages than non-exporting industries and firms) are as
high as 18 percent. Riker (2010) estimates that workers employed in U.S. export-intensive
manufacturing industries earned approximately 18 percent more than similar workers employed
in domestically-oriented manufacturing industries between 2006 and 2008. In follow-up work,
Riker and Thurner (2011) demonstrate that the relationship holds in services industries as well.
5
Controlling for industry differences, Bernard, Jensen, Redding, and Schott (2007) document a 6-
percent exporter wage premium in 2002: the average annual wage at exporting manufacturing
firms is 6 percent higher than the average annual wage at domestically-oriented manufacturing
firms.
5
In an update on this line of research, Riker (2015) estimates that workers employed in export-intensive
manufacturing industries earn a premium of 16.3 percent, and that workers employed in export-intensive services
industries earn a premium of 15.5 percent based on 2014 data.
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
TFP Growth Average
Wages
Labor
Productivity
Value Added
Per Worker
Capital
Intensity
Export-Intensive Non-Export-Intensive
Figure 2: Characteristics of Export-Intensive and
Non-Export-Intensive Industries, 1989-2009
Note: The ratio to the industry average is calculated as follows. Each industry’s
characteristic is measured relative to the industry average within the year and then averaged
over the 1989-2009 period and across export-intensive and non-export-intensive industry groups.
Source: National Bureau of Economic Research-Center for Economic Studies, Manufacturing
Industry Database; U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics; CEA Calculations.
Ratio to the Industry Average
16
Source
Time Period
(s ector)
Wa ge Varia bl e
(a ggregati on)
Export Vari able
(a ggregati on)
Es timated Exporter
Wa ge Premi um
(i n percent)
Control Va riables
Bernard a nd Jensen (1995)
1976-1987
(ma nufa cturing)
Average annual
wage (pla nt)
Exporter dummy
(pla nt)
4.5
Capita l per worker
Hours per worke r
Plant s ize
Plant a ge
Multi pl ant dummy
Indus try Fixed Effects
Region Fixed Effects
Yea r Fixed Effects
Bernard a nd Jensen (1995)
1976-1987
(ma nufa cturing)
Average annual
wage (pla nt)
Exporter dummy
(pla nt)
1.7
Capita l per worker
Hours per worke r
Plant s ize
Firm Fixed Effects
Yea r Fixed Effects
Bernard a nd Jensen (1999)
1984
(ma nufa cturing)
Average annual
wage (pla nt)
Exporter dummy
(pla nt)
14.8
Plant s ize
Indus try Fixed Effects
State Fi xed Effects
Bernard a nd Jensen (1999)
1987
(ma nufa cturing)
Average annual
wage (pla nt)
Exporter dummy
(pla nt)
9.3
Plant s ize
Indus try Fixed Effects
State Fi xed Effects
Bernard a nd Jensen (1999)
1992
(ma nufa cturing)
Average annual
wage (pla nt)
Exporter dummy
(pla nt)
9.3
Plant s ize
Indus try Fixed Effects
State Fi xed Effects
Bernard, Jense n, Redding, a nd
Schott (2007)
2002
(ma nufa cturing)
Average annual
wage (fi rm)
Exporter dummy
(fi rm)
6.0
Firm s i ze
Indus try Fixed Effects
Rike r (2010)
2006-2008
(ma nufa cturing)
Weekly earni ngs
(i ndividual )
Export share
(i ndus try)
18.0
Indus try import s ha re
Individual educa tion
Individual a ge/a ge -s quared
Dummy for s al es /offi ce
occupati ons
Dummy for uni on partici pa tion
Gender
Race
Dummy for l ives in metro a rea
Rike r and Thurner (2011)
2006-2008
(s ervices )
Weekly earni ngs
(i ndividual )
Export-intens ive
dummy (industry)
15.8
Dummy for i ndividual a ge>=35
Dummy for coll ege graduate
Dummy for white col la r
occupati on
Gender
Race
Yea r Fixed Effects
Rike r (2015)
2014
(ma nufa cturing)
Weekly earni ngs
(i ndividual )
Export-intens ive
dummy (industry)
16.3
Dummy for i ndividual a ge>=35
Dummy for coll ege graduate
Dummy for gradua te degree
Gender
Race
State Fi xed Effects
Rike r (2015)
2014
(s ervices )
Weekly earni ngs
(i ndividual )
Export-intens ive
dummy (industry)
15.5
Dummy for i ndividual a ge>=35
Dummy for coll ege graduate
Dummy for gradua te degree
Gender
Race
State Fi xed Effects
Table 4: Summary of Export Wage Premium Literature
Note: The estimated exporter wage premia presented in this table are not directly comparable across rows, due to differences in the variables of interest, differences in control variables, and
differences in the estimation methodology.
17
Table 4 summarizes the literature on the U.S. exporter wage premium, as adapted from Table 1
in Schank, Schnabel, and Wagner (2004). Bernard and Jensen (1995) consider plant-level data on
the manufacturing industry, and ask how a given plant’s export status (a binary indicator for
whether the plant exports or not) relates to the plant’s average wage payments, controlling for
industry, region, and year effects, as well as other plant-specific variables (capital per worker,
hours per worker, plant size, plant age, and whether the plant is part of a multi-plant firm). The
interpretation of their estimated exporter wage premium is then that exporting plants pay higher
average wages than observationally-equivalent non-exporting plants located in the same region
and producing in the same industry and time-period. Riker (2010), by contrast, takes a different
approach. The author matches individuals to the industries in which they work, and relates the
individual’s earnings to her industry’s export share. His analysis controls for the worker’s location,
as well as several worker-level characteristics that influence wages, such as education, age, union
participation, gender, race, and binary variables for whether the worker is employed in a white-
collar profession and whether the worker lives in a metro area (both of which typically pay higher
wages). The interpretation of his estimated exporter wage premium is then that workers
employed in high export share industries report higher earnings than observationally-identical
workers, living in the same state, who work for low export share industries.
Therefore, it is important to note that the estimated wage differentials reported in Table 4 are
not directly comparable across rows, due to differences in the main variables of interest,
differences in control variables, and differences in the estimation methodologies, and should be
viewed as complementary estimates. On the one hand, estimates like those from Bernard and
Jensen (1995) inform us about average wages at exporting plants relative to non-exporting
plants, and estimates like those in Riker (2010) inform us about an individual worker’s wages
depending on whether the worker is employed in an exporting industry or not. In what follows,
CEA considers both cases.
Average Wages
Table 5 reports coefficients relating trade to average wages, following the same estimation
strategy that we employed in our analysis of trade and productivitythat is, we relate industry-
level exports to the industry’s average wage over the 1990s and 2000s, akin to the work in
Bernard and Jensen (1995) given data constraints. Controlling for time-invariant industry and
year factors, as well as industry size and imports, the results are suggestive of wage gains
associated with exporting, including for production workers. Notably, a 10 percent increase in
exports is correlated with a 0.1 percent increase in the industry average production wage,
suggesting average wages for production workers were about 4 percent higher than they would
have been in the absence of strong increases in U.S. export activity. This corresponds to about
$1,380 in increased earnings (in 2009 dollars) for the average production worker in the average
industry, or $1,520 in today’s dollars.
18
Individual Wages
How can exporters and non-exporters offer persistently different wages in the same product
categories? Several explanations for this feature of the data have surfaced in the literature. If
labor markets are assumed to be competitive, it is likely that while average wages at exporters
are higher, individual wages at exporters are not. Instead, it is likely that exporters hire a
systematically different type of worker; that is, more skilled workers who would earn higher
wages on average regardless of where they workthat is, at both exporters and non-exporters.
Explanations for why exporters require a higher-skilled labor force include the technological
requirements of exporting (Yeaple 2005; Bustos 2007, 2011) and that exporters produce higher
quality goods (Verhoogen 2008).
The point that wage differences between exporters and non-exporters persist even after
controlling for the observable characteristics of workers suggests departures from perfect
competition in the labor market. Amiti and Davis (2012) propose a fair-wages, rent-sharing
storythat is, exporters earn higher profits than non-exporters, which are then shared with their
workers. Alternatively, Davis and Harrigan (2011) and Frías, Kaplan, and Verhoogen (2009)
suggest that exporters may pay efficiency wagesas higher quality products require higher
quality workers, exporters pay efficiency wages to induce effort from workers. Finally, Davidson,
Matusz, and Shevchenko (2008) and Helpman, Itskhoki, and Redding (2010) argue for search and
matching frictions in the labor market. Due to complementarities between firm productivity and
worker ability, the more productive exporting firms have an incentive to screen for workers
above a given ability threshold. As higher ability workforces are harder to replace (i.e., the
screening cost is higher), multilateral bargaining over wages leads to higher wages at exporting
firms, even for very similar workers.
In order to account for some of the observable differences across workers who sort into exporting
industries, in Table 6, we consider a simple analysis using data on individual-level annual earnings
Log Average Wage Log Average Production Wage
Log Exports
0.007 0.010*
(0.004) (0.006)
Indus try Fi xed Effects YES YES
Yea r Fixed Effects YES YES
Control for Imports YES YES
Control for Indus try Si ze YES YES
Observa tions 7,961 7,961
Table 5: Trade and Average Wages
Note: Average wages are defined as total payroll per employee. Average production wages are defined as total production payroll
per production worker. Industry size is defined as the inflation-adjusted value of total shipments by U.S. firms. Robust standard
errors, clustered at the industry level, are in parentheses. *** denotes significance at the 1-percent level, ** denotes significance at the
5-percent level, and * denotes significance at the 10-percent level. The panel dataset comprises over 370 industries over the 1989-
2009 period. Industries are defined according to NAICS and are disaggregated to the six-digit level.
Source: Data on payroll, production payroll, employment, production employment, total shipments, and industry-specific price
indices are from the NBER M anufacturing Industry Database. Data on imports and exports by industry from 1989-2006 are from the
U.C. Davis Center for International Data. Data on imports and exports by industry from 2007-2009 are from the Foreign Trade
Division of the U.S. Census Bureau.
19
from the Current Population Survey (CPS) for the years 1989 to 2009. Closely following the work
in Riker (2010), the data match individual workers to the industries in which they work. The
regression then relates the level of exports in an industry to the individual’s earnings. Even when
controlling for differences in worker characteristics such as gender, education, race, and age,
differences in workers’ employment through industry fixed effects, and differences in workers
locations through state fixed effects, CEA confirms an exporter wage premium. CEA’s analysis
suggests that the strong increase in exports over the 1990s and 2000s translates into an
additional $1,300 in annual earnings for workers in today’s dollars.
6
Foster Access to Foreign Markets Without Outsourcing
A common criticism of U.S. FTAs is that U.S. firms will shift production and employment away
from the United States to our trading partners, assumed to have lower labor standards and lower
wages, in order to cut labor costs by effectively sending U.S. jobs abroad.
One motivation for FDI is to circumvent barriers to sales abroadso to the degree that trade
agreements eliminate these barriers they make it easier to produce in the United States and
export abroad.
In addition, to the degree that trade agreementsdirectly or indirectlyraise labor standards
they can reduce some of the incentives that lead to outsourcing. Relying on data across many
countries over the 1980s and 1990s, Palley (2005) makes the case that higher labor standards are
6
More importantly, our analyses in Table 5 and Table 6 find no statistical relationship between increases in imports
and earnings. Any potential downside to workers’ wages due to import competition appears to be offset by the
benefits of increased imports of intermediate inputs (Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg 2008).
Log Annua l Ea rnings
Log Exports 0.012*
(0.007)
Indus try Fixed Effects YES
State Fi xed Effects YES
Year Fixed Effects YES
Control for Imports YES
Control for Industry Size YES
Observa ti ons 224,055
Table 6: Trade and Individual Wages
Source: Data on earnings by industry are from the U.S. Census Bureau, Current
Population Survey, as downloaded from the IPUMS-CPS, University of Minnesota.
Data on imports and exports by industry from 1989-2006 are from the U.C. Davis Center
for International Data. Data on imports and exports by industry from 2007-2009 are
from the Foreign Trade Division of the U.S. Census Bureau. Data on total shipments by
industry are from the NBER M anufacturing Industry Database.
Note: Robust standard errors, clustered at the industry-year level, are in parentheses. ***
denotes significance at the 1-percent level, ** denotes significance at the 5-percent
level, and * denotes significance at the 10-percent level. The panel dataset comprises 75
industries over the 1989-2009 period. Industries are defined according to the 1990
Census Bureau industrial classification system.
20
associated with higher wages. Olney (2013) documents that foreign investment is responsive to
labor market standards in other countries. Using data on FDI abroad by U.S. companies, the
author finds that Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries
with fewer employment protections received more U.S. FDI, offering some suggestive evidence
of a wider globalization-inspired race-to-the-bottom on employment protections.
7
This logic is
why current and future U.S. trade agreements directly embed strong and enforceable labor
commitments into their main texts (see Section IV for more information on current trade
negotiations). Moreover, the results in Palley (2005) and Olney (2013) together suggest that by
increasing enforceable labor standards, and thus increasing wages, abroad though our trade
agreements, the United States can potentially curb the outsourcing of American jobs.
Figure 3 summarizes the evolution of the stock of U.S. FDI in our free trade partners before and
after the enactment of all 14 FTAs (across 20 countries).
8
For a baseline comparison, the analysis
also presents the evolution of the stock of U.S. FDI in non-FTA partners before and after our FTAs
entered into force. By construction, time zero is the date of entry into force of the agreement.
Our analysis of the relationship between U.S. trade agreements and outsourcing documents that
the stock of U.S. FDI in our FTA partners shows no notable increase after enactment of the
agreement relative to the increase in U.S. FDI in our non-FTA partners post-enactment.
Specifically, looking at GDP-weighted averages of the stock of investment over time, Figure 3
shows that, on average, U.S. FDI in our FTA partners grew by 6.3 percent per year in the five years
7
The employment protections measure used in the paper is only available for OECD countries, and thus many less-
developed countries are not included in the sample. However, that the paper finds an economically significant
relationship among OECD countries suggests that the relationship identified may be even stronger among a wider
set of countries.
8
The analysis that follows uses data from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) on direct investment positions
valued on a historical cost basis. According to Ibarra-Caton and Mataloni (2014), the historical-cost value largely
reflects prices at the time of the investment.
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Years from FTA Enforcement
Stock of Real FDI as Percent of FDI at FTA Enforcement
GDP-Weighted Average
across All Countries
Except FTA Partners
GDP-Weighted Average
across FTA Partners
Figure 3: Stock of Real U.S. FDI Abroad
Around U.S. Free Trade Agreements
Note: All values in real 2009 dollars, deflated using the U.S. GDP deflator.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Direct Investment Position; International Monetary Fund,
World Economic Outlook; CEA Calculations.
21
pre-FTA enforcement, close to the growth rate of U.S. FDI in our non-FTA partners in the five
years leading up to FTA enforcement (8.1 percent per year). There was essentially no trajectory
change in the annualized growth rate of U.S. FDI in our FTA partners in the five years following
FTA enactment (at 8.4 percent).
Given that one motivation for FDI abroad is to circumvent foreign trade barriers in order to serve
the foreign market, this is perhaps not surprising. In fact, some FDI may have been replaced by
U.S. exports to those markets post-FTA enforcement (as is suggested in Figure 7-5 of CEA
(2015a)), offsetting other potential increases in U.S. FDI associated with the liberalization of rules
on overseas investment in the new FTA. Therefore, the evidence in Figure 3 suggests that U.S.
firms do not increase net outsourcing when the United States enters FTAs. Although some
production could shift offshore to take advantage of new FTA rules, other production that would
have shifted offshore could end up staying in the United States, thanks to our improved access
to foreign markets.
Figure 4 reports the stock of U.S. FDI in China’s free trade partners. In this case, the data show
unambiguously that when China enters into FTAs, U.S. firms send more foreign investment
abroad (outsource more) to China’s free trade partners. Likely, U.S. companies take advantage
of the preferential access to the Chinese marketa key spoke in the global supply chain
without any countervailing incentives to increase production in the United States (due to reduced
trade barriers abroad). Specifically, while the stock of U.S. FDI to China’s FTA partners and non-
FTA partners grew by around 9-10 percent per year before China’s FTAs entered into force, real
growth of U.S. FDI in Chinese FTA partners increased to 20 percent per year after China’s
agreements entered into force, without any comparable change in the growth rate of U.S. FDI in
China’s non-FTA partners.
The trends documented in the previous two charts are further supported by data on other
measures of multinational activity around U.S. and Chinese FTAs.
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Years from FTA Enforcement
Stock of Real FDI as Percent of FDI at FTA Enforcement
GDP-Weighted Average
across All Countries
Except FTA Partners
GDP-Weighted Average
across FTA Partners
Figure 4: Stock of Real U.S. FDI Abroad
Around Chinese Free Trade Agreements
Note: All values in real 2009 dollars, deflated using the U.S. GDP deflator.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Direct Investment Position; International Monetary Fund,
World Economic Outlook; World Bank, World Development Indicators; CEA Calculations.
22
There are many potential explanations for the descriptive evidence presented in the figures
abovefor example, there are differences in the types of countries that the U.S. engages with in
FTAs as compared with the types of countries with which China engages. Nevertheless, the trends
in the data are broadly consistent with the idea that U.S. FTAs do not actually encourage
outsourcing abroad. Instead, what may increase the outsourcing of American jobs is to remain in
the status quo; that is, without the United States to set high-quality labor standards around the
world, other countries enter into FTAs of their own and become magnets for outsourcing from
the United States. Further research on the relationship between trade agreements, FDI, and jobs
can help to elucidate these effects.
9
Development Effects of Trade
The United States engages in international trade and trade agreements to increase market-access
opportunities for U.S. businesses and workers and to lower prices and increase options for U.S.
consumers. In addition to these benefits, it is important to recognize the positive impact trade
has on global growth and security. The United States benefits directly when the rest of the world
is more prosperous and secureproviding a bigger and more stable market for American
exports. U.S. trade policy also has implications for labor rights in our trading partners, gender
equality, and environmental sustainability.
Increased Economic Growth
When countries specialize in the goods and services they can produce relatively efficiently and
trade for the rest, world production and consumption increase as existing global resources are
more effectively utilized. Simple international trade theory, therefore, suggests that increased
international trade can boost incomes. However straightforward this may seem, it is actually
quite difficult to discern empirically a causal relationship between trade and income. For
instance, countries may trade more because they are richer. Richer countries have better trading
infrastructure, such as good ports, and better access to information about opportunities abroad.
The fundamental challenge for statistical inference, then, is that while trade may affect income,
income also affects trade.
An extensive body of work examines the empirical association between trade openness and per
capita income growth. Frankel and Romer (1999) were among the first to attempt to establish a
causal picture of the impact of trade on income, arguing that the geographic placement of
countries provides a way to isolate a component of trade that is unrelated to income except
through its effect on trade. The authors use the distance between countries to predict the
amount of their bilateral trade, relying on the well-established relationship that proximity is a
strong predictor of trade flows (the so-called “gravity model”). Because a component of trade
flows isolated in this manner is highly correlated with income, the authors conclude that trade
has a positive causal effect on income.
9
Please see CEA (2015b) for further discussion of the relationship between FTAs and outsourcing.
23
Recent work argues that this approach should be refined to reflect that the distance between
countries may be related to non-trade determinants of income. For example, as documented by
Acemoglu et al. (2001), current economic development may depend directly on early economic
differences that have persisted over time, for example, differences related to geography and
climate. Changes in economic distance can help to isolate the impact of transportation costs on
income as these operate through the trade channel. Feyrer (2009a) relies on a unique event in
recent world history to identify changes in distance between country-pairsthe closure and re-
opening of the Suez Canal between 1967 and 1975. For some countries, this increase in sea
distance was substantial, and trade between such country-pairs dropped by 20 percent. Since
some country-pairs were not affected by the closing, it offers a unique experiment to test how
trade impacts income. The author concludes that every dollar of increased trade raises income
by about 25 cents.
Relying on another unique measure of time-varying distance between countries to predict
international trade, Feyrer (2009b) documents again the importance of international trade for
incomes. In this second paper, the author recognizes that the rapid progress in aircraft
technology in recent years dramatically changed the effective distances between countries
goods that previously had to circumvent large land masses by ship, can now travel by air via the
great circle distance. These changes, therefore, differentially benefited pairs of countries linked
by relatively short air routes as compared with sea routes. Using country-specific, time-varying
measures of sea distance and air distance, the author concludes that trade has a significant
positive effect on income, such that a 1 percent increase in trade raises real income by 0.5
percent.
Trade’s potential to raise real income growth in U.S. trading partners holds substantial potential
benefits for us. Growth in our trading partners increases the demand for U.S. exported goods.
Figure 5 illustrates the strong correlation between growth in U.S. exports and growth in the rest
of the world.
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
-4 -2 0 2 4 6
Figure 5: U.S. Export Growth vs. Foreign GDP Growth,
2000-2014
Real U.S. Export Growth, Percent Year-Over-Year
Trade-Weighted Foreign GDP Growth, Percent Year-Over-Year
Note: Data displayed are quarterly year-over-year growth rates.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts; National Sources
via Haver Analytics.
24
Poverty
The world has made historic progress in reducing poverty in recent decades. The total number of
poor people around the world fell by nearly half a billion between 2005 and 2010, and the
numbers are estimated to fall further in coming years at rates never before seen in history
(Chandy and Gertz 2011). Largely due to growth in China and India, across-country global income
inequality recently witnessed the first decline since the Industrial Revolution (Milanovic 2013). A
range of research shows that trade has played a role in these developments.
Hanson (2007) investigates the case of Mexico in the decade surrounding the implementation of
the North American Free Trade Agreement between Canada, Mexico, and the United States.
Using state-level variation, the author documents that individuals born in states with high-
exposure to globalization have relatively higher wages than individuals born in states with low-
exposure to globalization. McCaig (2011) uses the 2001 U.S.-Vietnam Bilateral Trade Agreement
(BTA) to study the effects of increased market access to rich countries on poverty in developing
countries and finds that a one standard deviation decrease in provincial tariffs is associated with
a two-year rate of poverty reduction of between 33 and 40 percent. By contrast, work by
Topalova (2007, 2010) on India’s 1991 trade liberalization provides a different view. Although the
incidence of poverty in rural India fell 13 percentage points around the liberalizationfrom 37
percent in 1987 to 24 percent in 1999areas of that country more exposed to trade experienced
progress toward poverty reduction that was not as rapid as other areas.
Better Working Conditions
A common argument against trade integration with countries in the developing world is the poor
labor standards of those countries. However, research finds that expanding access to U.S.
markets promotes higher-quality employment in less-developed countries as workers shift from
informal to formal employment, with little empirical evidence that local tariff reductions have an
offsetting effectmeaning that the forces unleashed by trade itself complement the effort to
include enforceable labor standards in our FTAs.
A recent paper by McCaig and Pavcnik (2014) finds that employment shifts from the household
business (informal) sector to the formal enterprise sector in Vietnam in the aftermath of large
U.S. tariff reductions as part of the U.S.-Vietnam BTA. Similarly, Paz (2014) reports that decreases
in foreign market tariffs decrease domestic informal employment in Brazil, while early work by
Goldberg and Pavcnik (2003), supported in Menezes-Filho and Muendler (2011), finds no
evidence of a link between declining import tariffs in Brazil and informal employment. More
importantly, work by Edmonds and Pavcnik (2005) documents a decrease in child labor
associated with increased international trade in Vietnam.
This is important because jobs in the informal sector are associated with lower wages, lower
employee benefits, worse working conditions, and lower job quality. McCaig and Pavcnik (2014)
report that workers in household businesses earn about 14 percent less than observationally
equivalent workers in the formal sector (in the same industry, province, and occupation).
Workers that switch to formal work (controlling for unobserved worker characteristics) earn
about 5 percent more than when they worked in a household business. Relying on information
25
from the Colombian National Household Survey, Goldberg and Pavcnik (2003) offer evidence that
informal sector work is associated with lower job and workplace satisfaction, very few benefits,
lower incidence of job training, and higher uncertainty about duration of employment. Formal
workers are more likely to receive individual benefits such as health coverage, dental coverage,
vacations, incentive bonuses, maternity leave, unemployment benefits and pensions, sick leave,
transportation benefits, insurance, and family subsidies. In fact, 83 percent of informal workers
report receiving no benefits through their jobthis number is only 4 percent for formal workers.
Therefore, trade agreements that expand U.S. market access for countries at a lower level of
development can provide a market-based approach to improving labor conditions in the
developing world.
10
High standard U.S. trade agreements also contain commitments to promote
and enforce workers’ rights. In fact, Dewan and Ronconi (2014) analyze whether FTAs signed
between the United States and Latin American countries during the last decade produced higher
enforcement of labor regulations. Their estimates suggest that signing an FTA with the United
States increased both inspection resources (the number of inspectors) and inspection activities
(the number of inspections).
In addition, recent studies by the Bureau of International Labor Affairs (ILAB) of the U.S.
Department of Labor (DOL) assess the advancement of U.S. preferential trading partners in
combating the worst forms of child labor (ILAB 2012, 2013, 2014), as required by the Trade and
Development Act of 2000. Table 7 presents simple statistics based on data in these reports.
11
Across all three years, U.S. FTA partners were more likely than non-FTA partners to be assessed
by DOL as having “significantly advanced” in combating child labor. In particular, in 2013, 36
percent of U.S. FTA partners “significantly advanced,” while only 7 percent of non-FTA partners
“significantly advanced.” In fact, five of the 13 countries that DOL assessed as having “significantly
advanced” are U.S. FTA partners. Meanwhile, while approximately 11 percent of non-FTA
partners were assessed in 2013 as having made “no advancement,” no U.S. FTA partners were in
this category. Over all three years of data availability, U.S. FTA partners were less likely to make
“no advancement”.
10
Salem and Rozental (2012) provide a review of the literature on labor standards and trade.
11
Admittedly, these data provide only suggestive correlative evidence, and cannot be used by themselves to infer a
causal relationship.
26
In addition to the assessments in each year, Table 7 also documents that as a group FTA partners
were more likely to earn improved assessments over time. Notably, between 2011 and 2013, the
likelihood that an FTA partner “significantly advanced” increased by 27 percentage points, as
compared to only a 6 percentage point increase for non-FTA partners. Moreover, in the three
years of data, no FTA partner was ever assessed to have regressed in combating child labor. By
contrast, between 2011 and 2012, 9 percent of non-FTA partners regressed, and between 2012
and 2013, 16 percent of non-FTA partners saw downgraded assessments.
Finally, though most U.S. FTAs entered into force long before DOL began reporting on countries’
advancement in combating the worst forms of child labor, two countries (Colombia and Panama)
entered into free trading arrangements with the United States over the period of assessment.
Interesting, although with no necessary implication of a causal relationship, is the fact that
Colombia’s assessment improved to “significantly advanced” in 2012, the year it entered into an
FTA with the United States, from “minimal advancement” the year before. Similarly, Panama
achieved “moderate advancement” in 2012, the year it entered into an FTA with the United
States, as compared to “minimal advancement” the year before.
Stronger Environmental Protection
Trade agreements can raise environmental standards in countries that otherwise would not be
motivated to raise standards on their own. In fact, the United States has a long history of pursuing
mutually supportive trade and environmental policies, and has found that strong, enforceable
environmental provisions pursued as part of our bilateral and regional trade agreements can help
raise environmental standards in our trading partners, leveling the playing field for workers and
businesses in America.
In addition to this values-driven approach to trade policy, there are two broad channels through
which trade can impact the environment: by changing the level of economic activity within
trading countries (known as the “scale effect”), and by changing the composition of economic
activity among trading countries (known as the “composition effect”). In each channel, there are
ways in which trade can help encourage sustainable development and promote environmental
protection.
FTA
Partners
non-FTA
Partners
FTA
Partners
non-FTA
Partners
FTA
Partners
non-FTA
Partners
Percent of Countries identified as:
No Advancement
8.3 17.5 7.1 10.3 0.0 10.7
Minima l Adva ncement
33.3 44.4 14.3 37.6 21.4 28.1
Moderate Adva ncement
50.0 37.3 57.1 46.2 42.9 54.5
Signi ficant Adva ncement
8.3 0.8 21.4 6.0 35.7 6.6
Obs ervations
12 126 14 117 14 121
Table 7: U.S. Free Trade Agreements and Child Labor
2011
2012
2013
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Findings on the Worst Forms of Child Labor , 2011-2013.
27
Scale Effect
It is well-established that increases in trade activity among countries go hand in hand with
increases in their overall economic activity. Environmentalists often point to this increase as a
cause for worry. A greater scale of economic activity likely means increases in transportation,
shipping, production, and consumptionall pollution-emitting activities. Note, however, that
much of this concern would apply to any policy that increases productivity growth, including
expanded research and education.
Higher productivity is associated with higher real incomes. Greater prosperity, in turn, can benefit
the environment in multiple ways. Higher real incomes create opportunities for investment in
R&D in clean technology, allowing countries to “clean-up” production techniques. Higher real
incomes can also generate greater ability and willingness to adopt, enforce, and pay for higher
standards of environmental quality. For example, with more disposable income, families might
be willing to pay a little extra to buy a hybrid car, or install solar panels for home-electricity
generation.
Ultimately, increased economic activity both generates and curbs pollution; the overall effect on
the environment depends on the relative magnitudes of each change. Empirical studies have
produced relatively consistent results showing that trade does increase pollution, but also that
accompanying emissions reductions from cleaner technology are enough to offset that increase.
For instance, Antweiler, Copeland, and Taylor (2001) remark that if trade liberalization raises GDP
per capita by 1 percent, then pollution concentrations fall by about 1 percent. The authors
decompose this effect as follows: a 1 percent increase in the scale of economic activity raises
pollution by around 0.5 percent, but the increase in income associated with international trade
drives down pollution by around 1.5 percent. Similarly, Copeland and Taylor (2003) estimate the
technique elasticity of pollution reduction with respect to income to be negative and greater than
1 in absolute value; that is, a given increase in real income is associated with an even greater
reduction in pollution in percentage terms. Grether, Mathys, and de Melo (2010) analyze data on
62 countries and 7 manufacturing sectors and show that increases in worldwide trade flows
between 1990 and 2000 are associated with a 2 to 3 percent decrease in global sulfur dioxide
emissions. Further, they show that manufacturing industries have become much cleaner over
timewhile, globally, manufacturing’s employment and output levels rose 10 to 20 percent
between 1990 and 2000, manufacturing emissions decreased by 10 percent. In other words, the
evidence suggests that, likely due to a global shift toward cleaner technology, the net effect of
increased trade on pollution is less than or equal to zero.
Figure 6 provides a basic visual illustration to support the findings of the existing academic
literature. Looking at the relationship between the growth in world exports, world greenhouse
gas emissions, and world output, it is clear that on a global scale, emissions have increased along
with increases in trade and output, but at a much slower rate. Between 2002 and 2008, in
particular, though exports surged, emissions did not.
28
Looking at the data another way, Figure 7 shows that emissions per dollar exported have actually
decreased over time, illustrating the global shift toward cleaner production technologies.
Composition Effect
Compositional changes that occur in the economies of trading partners as trade promotes
production specialization are a second mechanism behind trade’s environmental impacts. A
popular assumption is that specialization will send the most heavily polluting industries from rich
countries with stricter environmental regulation to poor countries, which have relatively lax
regulation. Theoretically, this migration would lead to an increase in world pollution levels and
the creation of “pollution havens” in developing countries that, as exporters of the “dirtiest”
goods, would bear a disproportionate amount of global pollution burdens. In a worst-case
scenario, environmentalists say, a race-to-the-bottom in environmental regulation could ensue
0
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
400
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Exports
GDP
Emissions
Index, 1990=100
Note: Exports and GDP measured in real 2009 dollars, deflated using U.S. GDP deflator.
Emissions measured in metric tons of CO2 equivalent.
Source: World Resources Institute, CAIT; World Bank, World Development Indicators.
Figure 6: Global Exports, GDP, and
Greenhouse Gas Emissions, 1990-2011
2011
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Figure 7: Global Emissions per
Billion Dollars of Exports, 1990-2011
MtCO2e per Billion Dollars
Note: Exports in real 2009 dollars, deflated using U.S. GDP deflator. Emissions measured in
metric tons of CO2 equivalent.
Source: World Resources Institute, CAIT; World Bank, World Development Indicators.
2011
29
if developed countries were to see an incentive to slow down efforts to raise environmental
protection in an effort to forestall the “dirty” industries’ emigration. True, not all parties in a
trade relationship can specialize in the cleanest industries, but concerns about “pollution havens”
and races-to-the-bottom are belied by the empirical evidence. In fact, there is reason to believe
that compositional changes could actually yield net environmental benefits.
Developed countries tend to be the best equipped for production of high-polluting goods since
the most-polluting industries, which include the manufacture of chemicals, metals, and paper,
and oil refining, are capital intensive. The basic economic theory of comparative advantage
suggests that those industries belong in countries with abundant capitalthe richer, developed
countries. Poorer countries with less capital on hand are more likely to specialize in industries
that are more service-oriented and labor-intensive, and less polluting. If this is true, the
compositional effects of trade could actually lead to reductions in global emissions, as pollution-
intensive production would occur in countries with stricter standards.
Of course, the issue is slightly more complicated, as environmental regulation can increase the
marginal cost of production in polluting industries, driving them to less regulated countries.
According to a 1999 World Trade Organization (WTO) report, however, the increased marginal
cost of pollution abatement in developed countries is no more than 1 percent of production costs
for the average polluter (a maximum of 5 percent for the worst polluters). Such small costs are
likely not powerful enough to deter production and send it elsewhere and, according to the WTO,
the developed-country share of global production in polluting industries has remained relatively
constant at around 75 to 80 percent over the past few decades (Nordstrom and Vaughan 1999).
Regardless of environmental regulation, standard non-environmental comparative advantage
considerations seem to dominate location decisions.
Broader Inclusion and Participation
Trade promotes competition, which helps reduce discrimination and furthers social inclusion.
Research has documented a decrease in discrimination-based wage gaps based on gender, race,
and immigration status in the aftermath of increased trade. Research also confirms that greater
openness to trade, as measured by lower tariff rates, is correlated with better human-rights
conditions.
12
Gender and Racial Equality
Promoting equality is a key development goal in both the developing world and in the United
States. Importantly, since trade promotes international competition, it may also reduce firms’
leeway to discriminate against women and other traditionally disadvantaged groups. The classic
Becker (1957) model of discrimination predicts that costly discrimination cannot persist with
increased market competition. Therefore, as trade liberalization results in increased competition
in the domestic market, discrimination-based wage gaps should narrow.
12
Research also supports the idea that increased economic cooperation through trade improves political
cooperation, reducing worldwide violent conflict. See Chapter 7 of CEA (2015a) for further discussion.
30
In line with the theory, by investigating trade-affected manufacturing industries in the United
States between 1976 and 1993, Black and Brainerd (2004) find that the residual gender wage gap
narrowed more rapidly in initially more concentrated industries that experienced larger increases
in competition with trade reform than in initially more competitive industries. Klein, Moser, and
Urban (2010) confirm this result for the case of Germany, demonstrating that increasing exports
diminished the manufacturing gender wage gap in that country.
If trade promotes competition and reduces discrimination, we should see decreases in other non-
productive wage gaps. In fact, Essaji, Sweeney, and Kotsopoulos (2010) found that trade
exposure helped narrow the racial wage gap in the United States by about 1.4 percentage points
between 1983 and 1993 and Klein, Moser, and Urban (2010) document a similar decrease in the
wage discount suffered by immigrants in Germany.
Akin to our analysis of the exporter wage premium, CEA collected data from the CPS on annual
earnings of women and men in 3-digit NAICS industries in order to assess the impact of increased
international competition on the gender wage gap. For each industry, we calculate the gender
earnings ratio as the average wage across all women employed in the industry relative to the
average wage across all men employed in the industry. In the beverage and tobacco
manufacturing industry, female earnings are particularly low, reported to be only 18.7 percent
of average male earnings. Meanwhile, in textile product mills, average female wages are almost
3.5 times average male earnings. These industry-level gender wage gaps are then matched to
industry-level tariff rates for the years 1989-2009.
Table 8 reports coefficient estimates for a panel estimation with industry and year fixed effects
relating tariffs to the gender wage ratio, with the idea that decreasing tariffs increases foreign
competition in the industry, thereby reducing the gender wage gap. CEA’s estimates show that
industries with larger tariff declines over the 1990s and 2000s experienced larger relative income
gains for women. A 10 percentage point decrease in tariffs is associated with approximately a 1
percentage point increase in female annual earnings relative to male annual earnings. As we
remark earlier, average tariffs in the United States are already very low, and therefore, changes
in U.S. tariffs over this time period were also quite small. It is no surprise, then, that the
improvement in the gender wage gap that can be attributed to tariff changes is also very small.
While not large, it is another way that expanded trade integration produces benefits for middle-
class families. Moreover, the precision of our estimates is suggestive of the potentially larger
impact of trade on middle-class families and gender income inequality, once the full range of
competition-enhancing policy changes, beyond tariff changes, associated with new trade
agreements come into effect.
31
Democracy and Human Rights
Opponents of trade agreements with less-developed countries often point to human rights
abuses in those countries as reasons not to engage economically. Though assessing a causal
relationship between trade openness and democratic institutions, political liberties, or civil
liberties is difficult, the idea that globalization can promote the spread of democratic ideas goes
as far back as Kant (1795). The international exchange of goods and services allows for the
exchange of ideas and methods, promoting political competition. Alongside the natural force of
globalization, many current regional trade agreements also include provisions related to human
rights, such as privacy rights, political participation, due process, access to information, cultural
rights, indigenous rights, and access to affordable medicines (Aaronson and Chauffour 2011).
Does international trade foster democracy and human rights? Rigorous empirical research in
economics suggests the answer is yes.
López-Córdova and Meissner (2005) is among the best studies trying to estimate a link from trade
openness to democracy. Following the long literature estimating the link between trade and
income (discussed earlier), the authors employ a gravity model specification to obtain
instruments for international trade openness, using information dating back to 1870. Their work
reports a positive impact of trade openness on democratization. Democratization is proxied by
the composite index score from the Polity IV data set, which summarizes a country’s political
system based on competitiveness in executive recruitment, constraints on the executive, and
competitiveness in political participation. The authors note that “[b]etween 1920 and 1938
countries more exposed to international trade were less likely to become authoritarian.”
Eichengreen and Leblang (2006) also rely on the gravity model for their instrumental variables
analysis, which seeks to disentangle the two-way causality between democracy and trade. Like
López-Córdova and Meissner (2005), they find that trade openness promotes democracy. In the
Eichengreen and Leblang (2006) paper, a country is coded as democratic if it has elections where
Gender Earni ngs Ratio
Ta riff
-0.0741***
(0.0193)
Indus try Fixed Effects YES
Year Fixed Effects YES
Control for Industry Size YES
Observa ti ons 420
Table 8: Trade and the Gender Wage Gap
Note: Tariffs are the simple average of applied rates. Robust standard errors, clustered
at the industry level, are in parentheses. *** denotes significance at the 1-percent level, **
denotes significance at the 5-percent level, and * denotes significance at the 10-percent
level. The panel dataset comprises 21 industries over the 1990-2009 period. Industries
are defined according to NAICS and are disaggregated to the three-digit level.
Source: Data on earnings by gender and industry are from the U.S. Census Bureau,
Current Population Survey, as downloaded from the IPUM S-CPS, University of
Minnesota. Data on total shipments by industry are from the NBER Manufacturing
Industry Database. Data on tariff rates are from the World Integrated Trade Solution
database maintained by the United Nations Statistical Division.
32
more than one party competes. As this definition means that Croatia is as “democratic” as the
United Kingdom, the authors also employ a continuous democracy variable that captures the
length of time a country has been a democracy. Across both measures, trade is a strong predictor
of democratic institutions.
Beyond democratic political institutions, Sykes (2003) provides a compelling argument for human
rights as a “normal good”—that is, the growth in income that international trade provides will
promote human rights. Relying on data for 195 countries on average tariff rates and four
measures of the quality of human rights (the Humana Rating, from the 1991 Human Rights Guide;
the Economic Freedom Rating for 2000, prepared by the Wall Street Journal; the Freedom House
Political Rights Rating; and the Freedom House Civil Liberties Rating), Sykes (2003) confirms that
greater openness to trade, as measured by lower tariff rates, is correlated with better human-
rights conditions.
33
III. Sector-Specific Trends in U.S. Trade
As policy barriers in the U.S. and around the world come down, the United States is increasingly
more integrated with the rest of the world.
13
Exports and imports as a percentage of GDP have
roughly tripled in the decades since 1970. Still, in 2014 the United States remains a relatively
closed economy, as exports and imports represent only 13 percent and 16 percent of GDP,
respectively.
14
Part of this reflects still high NTBs to international trade and investment in the rest of the world,
particularly for trade in servicesa growing component of U.S. and international trade. Consider,
for example, the changing composition of U.S. exports from 1980 to the present, as depicted in
Figures 8a and 8b. Manufactured goods comprise the bulk of U.S. exports, consistently
representing around 60 percent of total U.S. goods and services exports. By contrast,
agriculture’s share of total exports declined from 15 percent in 1980 to only 6 percent in 2014,
while the share of services among total U.S. goods and services exports increased from 18
percent in 1980 to 30 percent in 2014. The share of other goods has also fallen over time, from
8 percent in 1980 to 4 percent in 2014.
The relatively strong growth of U.S. services exports since 1980, as compared to merchandise
exports (both manufactured and agricultural goods), is depicted in Figure 9. In real terms, U.S.
services exports have grown 6-times over, this growth picking up speed in 2000 with the digital
revolution. Real manufactured goods exports have almost quadrupled since 1980, while real
agricultural exports have grown by about 50 percent in the last three-and-a-half decades.
13
Please see Chapter 7 of CEA (2015a) for further background on U.S. and world trade.
14
By comparison, in 2014, respectively, Germany’s exports and imports represent 46 percent and 39 percent of its
GDP, and China’s exports and imports represent 25 percent and 22 percent of its GDP, respectively.
Manufactured
Goods
60%
Services
30%
Agricultural
Goods
6%
Other Goods
4%
Figure 8b: Composition of U.S. Exports, 2014
Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis, International
Services; U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States;
CEA Calculations.
Manufactured
Goods
59%
Services
18%
Agricultural
Goods
15%
Other Goods
8%
Figure 8a: Composition of U.S. Exports, 1980
Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis, International
Services; U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States;
CEA Calculations.
34
These sector-specific trends in U.S. exports are in part a reflection of broader changes in the U.S.
economy. Figure 10 depicts sector-specific shares of total U.S. GDP and total civilian employment
since 1947.
Services industries comprise about four-fifths of the U.S. economy, and employ over 80 percent
of American workers. More importantly, the shares of services in U.S. GDP and U.S. employment
have been steadily rising since the middle of the last century, growing over 20 percentage points
and almost 35 percentage points, respectively, since data collection began.
Meanwhile, the manufacturing sector currently makes up about 12 percent of the U.S. economy,
and employs roughly 8 percent of American workers. In sharp contrast to services, the shares of
manufacturing in U.S. GDP and U.S. employment have been steadily declining since the middle
Manufactured
Goods
Agricultural Goods
Services
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Figure 9: U.S. Exports of Goods and Services, 1980-2014
Index, 1980=100
Note: All values in real 2009 dollars, deflated using the U.S. GDP deflator.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau, Foreign Trade Statistics; Bureau of Economic Analysis, International
Services; U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States.
2014
0
1
2
3
4
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
1947 1954 1961 1968 1975 1982 1989 1996 2003 2010
Figure 10: Share of Employment and GDP in the Services,
Manufacturing, and Agricultural Sectors, 1947-2014
Percent
Services GDP
(left axis)
Services Employment
(left axis)
Agriculture
Employment
(right axis)
Agriculture GDP
(right axis)
Manufacturing Employment
(left axis)
Manufacturing GDP
(left axis)
Percent
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts; Bureau of Labor
Statistics, Household Survey and Payroll Survey.
35
of the last century. In fact, manufacturing’s share of the U.S. economy has more than halved since
its peak at around 28 percent of GDP in the early 1950s, when manufacturing employed roughly
one in every four American workers. Agriculture’s decline has been no less significant, though on
a much smaller scale, with agriculture’s share of the economy falling from 2 percent of GDP in
1977 to just over 1 percent of GDP in 2014, and agriculture’s share of employment falling from
around 3 percent since data collection began to around 1 percent today.
Part of the reason for these employment share trends is the comparatively rapid growth of labor
productivity in manufacturing and agriculture, as compared to services (see Figure 11). This high
productivity growth allows manufacturing prices to fall compared to the prices of services,
thereby reducing the overall weight of manufacturing value-added in national value-added.
Moreover, as people get richer, they increase spending on items like housing, as well as services
like health care, travel, and restaurants, more than they increase their spending on manufactured
goods such as cars or televisions. Therefore, services employment must increase to keep up with
this growing demand. These trends are apparent in all industrial countries.
In what follows, we consider the role of international trade in each of these three major
components of the U.S. economy.
The Rise of Services Trade
Despite the prevalence of services in the economy, there is a dearth of research investigating the
impact of international trade in services. The cross-border flow of physical goods is easy to
measure as goods pass through customs authorities. Services trade, on the other hand, is less
straightforward to document, as many services are delivered digitally and thus have no single
Manufacturing
Agriculture
Services
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
180
1947 1954 1961 1968 1975 1982 1989 1996 2003 2010
Thousands
Figure 11: Labor Productivity in Services, Manufacturing, and
Agricultural Sectors, 1947-2014
Thousands of Dollars per Worker
Note: All values in real 2009 USD, deflated using the U.S. GDP deflator.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, National Income and Product Accounts; Bureau of Labor
Statistics, Househould Survey and Payroll Survey.
36
point of crossing.
15
The General Agreement on Trade in Services, a WTO agreement that came
into force in 1995, defines four modes of services trade:
First, services trade occurs when a service produced in one country is consumed in
another country; for instance, when Hollywood movies show in theaters abroad.
Second, services trade occurs when consumers from abroad purchase local services, such
as when foreigners travel to the United States for vacation, for an education, or for health
care services.
The third mode of services trade occurs through FDI; for instance, when a U.S. bank opens
a branch abroad to offer financial services in other countries.
The fourth mode of services trade occurs when individual service providers from one
country travel to supply services in another country. An example would be an American
academic receiving a fee to present an educational seminar abroad.
Apart from limited data, the lack of research on services trade also reflects that services, which
require interaction between producers and customers, were long thought to be non-tradable
the classic example of the non-tradable service being the haircut. While haircuts are still unlikely
to be traded, the rapid rise in Internet access and capacity to move data around the world at low
cost has created entirely new export opportunities for services providers and American small
businesses. This growth in information technology and declining transportation costs have
facilitated a strong rise in trade in services like education, health care, tourism, as well as the
many business and professional services associated with trade in goods (telecommunications,
finance, distribution, insurance, and more). The spread of multinational firms and the worldwide
subdivision of production processes have also contributed to this rise.
In 2014, U.S. services exports measured approximately $710 billion, or 30 percent of total U.S.
exports, while imports of services were about $480 billion, or 17 percent of total U.S. imports.
Together, services trade accounted for almost 7 percent of U.S. GDP in 2014. As depicted in Figure
12, these levels reflect rapid growth since 1980; real U.S. services exports grew by 613 percent
over the 34-year period to 2014, or at a 5.6-percent average annual rate. The United States
maintains a strong and growing surplus in services.
15
The Economics and Statistics Administration of the U.S. Department of Commerce estimates that in 2011 over 60
percent of U.S. services exports and about 17 percent of total U.S. goods and services exports are delivered digitally
(Nicholson and Noonen 2014).
37
The BEA characterizes nine broad categories of tradable services: insurance; government;
financial; travel; maintenance and repair; telecom, computer, and information; transport;
intellectual property; and other business services. Figure 13 illustrates the composition of the
growth in real U.S. services exports since 1999. Though all categories have been growing in the
last decade and a half, contributing to the overall rise in U.S. services exports, real exports of
insurance services have been growing at the fastest pace, quadrupling between 1999 and 2014.
Real exports of financial services also increased, since detailed data collection began in 1999, by
over 200 percentfrom $24 billion to $82 billion in 2014, expressed in 2009 dollars.
Like tariffs on goods trade, the United States already maintains a relatively open services trade
regime. The OECD calculates a Services Trade Restrictiveness Index (STRI), to function as a tariff-
equivalent for services trade. The United States has relatively low services barriers to trade,
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
1980 1990 2000 2010
Billions of Dollars
Exports
Imports
Balance
Note: All values in real 2009 dollars, deflated using the U.S. GDP deflator. Data post-1998
are based on BEA's restructured U.S. Trade in Services series.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, International Economic Accounts; Haver Analytics.
Figure 12: U.S. Trade in Services, 1980-2014
2014
0
100
200
300
400
500
600
700
1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014
Travel Intellectual Property
Other Business Services Transport
Financial Services Telecom, Computer, & Information
Government Maintenance and Repair
Insurance Services
Figure 13: Composition of Services Exports Growth, 1999-2014
Billions of Dollars
Note: All values in real 2009 dollars, deflated using the GDP deflator.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, International Economic Accounts.
38
according to the OECD (see Figure 14). In fact, as compared to the sector average across the 40
countries analyzed by the OECD (34 OECD members, plus Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Russia,
and South Africa), the United States has lower barriers to services trade in 14 out of 18 different
service sectors. Liberalizing services trade through U.S. agreements around the world will unlock
new opportunities for American workers and businesses. In fact, Jensen (2011) reports that
services are still five times less likely to be exported than manufacturing products. If services
reached the same export potential as manufactured goods, U.S. exports could increase by as
much as $800 billion.
Manufacturing Rebound
In October 2014, President Obama issued a proclamation declaring a National Manufacturing
Day. At that time, the U.S. labor market had witnessed 56 months of consecutive job growth and
the unemployment rate stood at 5.8 percent, the lowest rate since before the Great Recession.
Since then, the positive trend has continued, with manufacturers creating 866,000 new jobs since
the sector’s turning point in 2010.
Today, the United States is increasingly competitive for manufacturing jobs, investment, and
exports. For the last three years, the United States has been ranked #1 in AT Kearney’s FDI
Confidence Index, and, in 2013, the United States surged past countries like China, Brazil, and
India, for the first time since 2002, to become the most attractive country for investment globally
(A.T. Kearney 2015). At the same time, U.S. exports of manufactured goods have increased by
over 40 percent, from $918 billion in 2009 to $1.3 trillion (measured in 2009 dollars) in 2014
far outpacing growth in total U.S. goods and services exports. This growth has reduced the U.S.
manufactured goods trade deficit by almost 20 percent since its peak in 2006.
However, despite the increasing competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing for investment and
exports, among critics of international trade and trade agreements a central concern is that
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
Lack of
Regulatory
transparency
Barriers to
competition
Other
discriminatory
measures
Restrictions to
movement of
people
Restrictions on
foreign entry
Figure 14: U.S. Services Trade Restrictiveness Index
by Sector and Policy Area, 2014
Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Average
Index
39
expanded trade might put the recent strength in U.S. manufacturing employment at risk.
16
But,
as Figure 15 illustrates, the past periods of major decline in manufacturing employment largely
coincide with economic recessions, not with new trade agreements. Conversely, manufacturing
growth has been an important part of the most recent economic recovery, and it has been fueled
by strong growth in manufacturing exports.
Manufacturing’s rebound since the Great Recession can also be seen in Figure 16. Starting in
2009, manufacturing output has increased as a share of U.S. value-added, in marked contrast to
the pattern seen in all other recent U.S. recessions.
16
For a discussion of the manufacturing employment effects of trade with China, please see Box 7-2 in CEA (2015a).
-250
-200
-150
-100
-50
0
50
100
150
-250
-200
-150
-100
-50
0
50
100
150
1 37 73 109 145 181 217 253 289 325 361 397 433 469
3 month moving average, thousands, seasonally adjusted
Note: Gray shading denotes recession.
Sources: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Payroll Survey; CEA Calculations
Figure 15: Monthly Change in Manufacturing Employment,
1975-2015
Mar-2015
1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015
40
The rapid growth of U.S. manufacturing exports has helped support this dramatic rebound in the
U.S. manufacturing sector coming out of the Great Recession. Sustaining this rapid growth in U.S.
manufacturing exports is why it is so important to bring down foreign barriers to U.S. exports:
increasing world demand for American-made manufactures is an integral component of growth
in U.S. manufacturing jobs and manufacturing wages.
Robust Agricultural Trade
International trade has always been important to U.S. farm and rural economies, from early
colonial days when tobacco and cotton were the most important export commodities, to today’s
exports of large amounts of grain, oilseeds, and processed foods. As documented in Figure 17,
exports of agricultural goods have displayed robust growth since 1990, with the value of those
exports more than doubling in real terms.
Though today agriculture accounts for a relatively small share of U.S. GDP, U.S. agricultural trade
accounts for 6 percent of all U.S. trade. In fact, agricultural exports have outpaced agricultural
imports in recent years, generating a surplus in agricultural trade (see Figure 17). This agricultural
trade surplus (at $43 billion in 2014) helps to offset some of the nonagricultural trade deficit.
Moreover, USDA’s Economic Research Service (ERS) estimates that each dollar of agricultural
exports stimulated another $1.22 in related business activity (ERS 2013). Therefore, in 2014 when
the United States exported $155 billion in agricultural goods, based on ERS calculations, total
economic output increased by almost $350 billion.
Since 1995, U.S. exports have expanded across a number of bulk and high-value product
categories, highlighting the importance of international trade for U.S. agriculture. In 2014,
oilseeds and pulses, horticulture products, and grains and feeds represented the largest export
categories for U.S. agriculture (see Figure 18).
0
20
40
60
80
100
120
140
160
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
Figure 17: U.S. Agricultural Trade, 1980-2014
Billions of Dollars
Note: All values in real 2009 dollars, deflated using the U.S. GDP deflator.
Source: U.S. Department of Agrigulture, Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States.
Exports
Balance
41
Foreign buyers account for a substantial share of the current production volume for many U.S.
commodities (see Figure 19). For example, in 2014 approximately one-half of the wheat, rice, and
soybeans produced in the United States were exported. Even more impressive, over two-thirds
of U.S. almond and walnut production was exported and about 80 percent of cotton and
pistachios.
In addition, trade opens up access to markets that put significantly higher value on products that
have little demand in the United States, offering U.S. producers a new overseas market revenue
source and further supporting farm and processor profitability. For example, according to the
Office of the Chief Economist (OCE) at USDA, in the meat sector, parts of a carcass have little or
no value to U.S. consumers, but are highly prized in some foreign markets. Chicken feet (or paws)
provide a case in point. There is little demand for chicken paws in the United States, so their
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
Oilseeds,
Pulses
Horticulture
Products
Grains,
Feeds
Livestock,
Poultry,
Dairy
Other Food,
Consumer
Oriented
Other
Figure 18: Top U.S. Agricultural Exports, 2014
Billions of Dollars
Note: Oilseeds include soybeans and soybean meal and oil. Horticulture products include fresh
and processed vegetables and whole and processed nuts. Grains and feeds include wheat, rice,
corn, feeds and fodders, and other coarse grains. Other includes cotton, tobacco, and other bulk
commodities.
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Service.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Cotton Pistachios Walnuts Almonds Wheat Rice Soybeans
Figure 19: Select U.S. Agricultural Exports
as a Share of Production, 2014
Percent
Note: Data are for marketing year 2013/14.
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Service.
42
domestic price is correspondingly lowonly 10 to 12 cents per pound. Since the opening of
China’s market, however, the majority of chicken paws have been shipped to China and other
overseas markets, where they can be sold for over 51 cents a poundin the price range of some
chicken leg quarters sold in the United States (OCE 2014). Beef trade offers similar examples,
with beef livers, beef tongue, and beef tripe earning premium prices in Egypt, Japan, and China,
respectively.
Finally, U.S. consumers benefit from the increased variety provided by imports (see Figure 20),
particularly fresh fruits and vegetables. About half of all U.S. agricultural imports are fruit,
vegetable, nut, and other horticultural products, which are now available year round thanks to
trade.
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
Horticulture
Products
Other Food,
Consumer
Oriented
Sugar, Oils,
Tropical
Products
Livestock,
Dairy,
Poultry
Other Grains,
Feeds
Figure 20: Top U.S. Agricultural Imports, 2014
Billions of Dollars
Note: Horticulture products include fresh and processed vegetables and whole and processed
nuts. Grains and feeds include rice, feeds and fodders, and other course grains. Sugar, oils, and
tropical products includes sweeteners and products, coffee, cocoa and chocolate, vegetable
oils, and rubber. Other includes tobacco and planting seeds.
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Service.
43
IV. Current Trade Negotiations
Despite the strong increases in U.S. trade over the last decades,
17
the potential gains from trade
for the United States are far from exhausted. Therefore, the United States has been focusing in
recent years on negotiations toward two major multi-continental FTAs: TPP would encompass 12
Pacific nations across the Asia-Pacific, and T-TIP is a proposed FTA between the United States and
the 28 member states of the European Union. The Administration’s trade agenda seeks to put
the United States at the center of an integrated trade zone covering nearly two-thirds of the
global economy and almost 65 percent of U.S. goods trade (see the map below). That will help
make America the world’s production platform of choice, increasing U.S. exports and attracting
more employers that want to invest in the United States, hire American workers, and sell
American goods and services to the world.
A key goal of U.S. FTAs is to secure tariff reductions abroad. The United States is already a very
open country. With almost 70 percent of imports crossing our borders duty-free, the trade-
weighted average applied tariff in the United States is a low 1.4 percent. By contrast, many of
our trading partners maintain relatively high tariffs. According to the World Bank, Vietnam’s
simple average applied tariff rate was 7.1 percent in 2010, 4.2 percentage points above the
equivalent U.S. tariff, and at 6.8 percent in 2009, Malaysia’s average tariff is also well above the
same rate in the United States. The spreads for specific industries can be much greaterfor
instance, U.S. businesses face tariffs of up to 30 percent on auto exports to Malaysia and over
700 percent on rice exports to Japan. Even among existing FTA partners, U.S. exporters to Canada
still face over-quota tariffs as high as 313 percent on dairy products and as high as 249 percent
on poultry products.
At the same time, tariffs are just one of many roadblocks to trade that governments put up. Trade
agreements bring about reductions in NTBs, while also liberalizing investment regimes and
services trade where NTBs are especially severe. Considering Figure 22, we note that the average
17
For more information on current U.S. trade and trade agreements, please refer to CEA (2015a).
44
STRI across TPP countries that belong to the OECD is higher than the STRI in the United States in
nine out of 18 service sectors. This average across TPP partners hides the much larger variation
in services barriers that the United States faces in serving TPP markets. For instance, the
maximum services trade barrier that the United States currently faces in prospective TPP trading
partners is higher than the U.S. STRI in 16 out of 18 service sectors. Note that the OECD reports
information on only six out of the 11 other TPP countries, suggesting that these differentials could
be even larger in the remaining five.
As a result, the main impact of new FTAs will be to reduce foreign barriers to U.S. exports, rather
than further opening U.S. markets to imports. Bringing down our trade partners’ tariffs and NTBs
is essential for American firms to be able to compete on a level playing field in the global
economy.
The Administration’s policy is to encourage trade agreements to promote a values-driven trade
regime that maximizes globalization’s benefits while addressing globalization’s problematic side-
effects. Enforceable environmental and labor commitments, included as a core part of our
agreements, can help to level the playing field for U.S. businesses and workers, while also
contributing to strong labor protections and greener policies worldwide. In addition, our trade
agreements ensure that American businesses remain competitive in a global market in which our
trading partners are also gaining preferential access to foreign markets through negotiations of
their own bilateral and regional agreements. The Administration’s efforts will also pave the way
for future high-standard agreements around the world, and trade pacts with TPP and T-TIP
countries will help advance U.S. strategic and geopolitical interests. Finally, it is important to
understand that these agreements are not meant to represent the end of the process. TPP is
explicitly designed to allow others to join in the future, and both TPP and T-TIP are intended to
spur further multilateral trade liberalization.
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
US OECD-Member TPP Average OECD-Member TPP Maximum
Figure 21: Services Trade Restrictiveness Index in the
United States and non-U.S. OECD-Member TPP countries, 2014
Note: Data for non-U.S. TPP include OECD members Australia, Canada, Chile, Japan, Mexico, and
New Zealand only.
Source: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, STRI.
Index
45
Trans-Pacific Partnership
TPP is a proposed regional FTA that the United States is negotiating with 11 other countries:
Australia, Brunei Darussalam, Canada, Chile, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru,
Singapore, and Vietnam. Based on the most recent data, TPP partners account for 37 percent of
world GDP, 11 percent of the world’s population, and 23 percent of world exports of goods and
services. In 2013, TPP countries received $698 billion in U.S. merchandise exports and $199 billion
in U.S. services exports, making the region as a whole the top export destination for the United
States. In addition, included among the partners are some of the fastest-growing economies in
the world; according to some measures, the number of middle-class consumers in Asia is
expected to grow to 3.2 billion by 2030 (Kharas and Gertz 2010), roughly ten times the projected
size of the North American middle classan enormous increase in the potential export market
for U.S. goods and services. The region is already an important location for U.S. investment; in
2013, U.S. companies invested $695 billion in the Asia-Pacific area. Petri, Plummer, and Zhai
(2012, 2013) estimate that TPP would increase world income over $220 billion (about 0.2
percent) and increase world exports by over $300 billion, or 1.1 percent, in 2025. For the United
States, the authors estimate TPP will increase GDP by over $75 billion, or approximately 0.4
percent, and U.S. exports by 4.4 percent, around $124 billion, by 2025.
TPP countries have expressed their intent to achieve a “comprehensive and high-standard” FTA
that will broadly liberalize regional trade and investment, strengthening economic ties between
the parties. In addition to addressing tariff barriers, TPP countries are seeking to address a range
of outstanding NTBs, such as import licensing restrictions, as well as to open services and
government procurement markets in the region. The United States and its partners are seeking
to negotiate rules that will provide transparent protections for investors and citizens, support the
digital economy by encouraging Internet access and cross-border data flows, address paperwork
and customs issues that hamper small-business exporters, promote innovation through strong
enforcement of intellectual property rights, and offer guidance on competitive practices
associated with state-owned enterprises.
In addition, when concluded, TPP will place strong workers’ rights commitments at the core of
the agreement, making them enforceable and subject to dispute settlement, as with other
commercial provisions. TPP will constitute the largest expansion of enforceable labor rights in
history, more than quadrupling the number of people around the world covered by enforceable
workplace standards. TPP will also contain strong commitments on the environment, including
commitments to protect our oceans, combat wildlife trafficking, and eliminate illegal logging. As
with the labor provisions of TPP, these commitments will be enforceable through dispute
settlement, allowing for trade sanctions against countries that fail to abide by the commitments.
TPP will also include a robust intellectual property rights framework to promote innovation, while
supporting access to innovative and generic medicines; secure market access for U.S. service
suppliers; include provisions that ensure that private sector workers and businesses are able to
compete on fair terms with state-owned enterprises; and contain obligations that will promote
a thriving digital economy, including rules on open Internet access.
46
Failing to secure a TPP agreement would place U.S. workers and businesses at a distinct
disadvantage, by allowing other countries to set the rules of the global trading systemrules that
would likely harm U.S. interests. Comprehensive trade agreements like TPP offer the United
States a way to shape globalization’s rules in the best interest of American workers and firms and
to ensure that global standards cover critically important areas like worker and environmental
protections.
Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership
The United States and the European Union already maintain the world’s largest bilateral trade
relationship. In 2013, together both regions account for nearly one-half of world GDP and about
42 percent of global exports of goods and services. Bilateral trade between the two regions
amounts to about $1 trillion annually. Based on the most recent data, U.S. companies have
approximately $2.4 trillion invested in the European Union, while European companies have $1.7
trillion invested in the United States. These already strong economic relationships would be
strengthened through the formalization of T-TIP.
Despite their large size and close ties, the European Union and the United States have not
achieved the full potential of their economic relationship. Therefore, negotiations toward the
ambitious T-TIP began in earnest in June 2013. Since tariff barriers between the two partners are
already relatively low, the agreement strives to increase market access by also addressing the
main NTBs. Importantly, both sides seek agreement on cross-cutting disciplines on regulatory
coherence and transparencyincluding early consultation on major regulations and use of
regulatory impact assessmentfor the development and implementation of efficient, cost-
effective, and more-compatible regulations for goods and services. Adoption and use of good
regulatory practices will ultimately raise the standards and promote trade beyond just the United
States and the European Union. In addition, the governments intend to commit to liberalize
services trade, promote FDI, and cooperate on the development of rules and policies on global
issues of common concern.
47
V. Conclusion
Through trade linkages, the world’s economies are more interdependent than at any time in
history. This interdependence has been supported not only by steep declines in the costs of
international communication and shipping, but also by a reduction in governmental barriers to
the cross-border movement of goods, services, and investment. Increasingly, economies are
linked by production processes that cross international borders so as to minimize costs by better
exploiting local comparative advantages.
The post-World War II process of globalization has delivered important benefits for U.S.
consumers, workers, and businesses by increasing economies’ productivity, opening new
markets for exports, and expanding the range of products available for purchase. Expanded trade
has also improved peoples’ lives in other, indirect ways, for example, raising living and working
standards in other countries, and locking in meaningful environmental protections.
Domestic U.S. policies that support the middle class are essential to help our economy take
advantage of the opportunities afforded by trade along, as are measures to counteract
potentially negative side effects. But beyond these purely domestic safeguards, an evolving
structure of multilateral and regional agreements has worked to lower international trade
barriers while reining in unfair trade practices. The WTO is central to that effort. In addition, the
Administration is pursing comprehensive, high-quality trade agreements that provide U.S.
exporters with enhanced market access while insisting that our trading partners do not compete
on the basis of low labor or environmental standards.
48
References
A.T. Kearney. 2015. “Connected Risks: Investing in a Divergent World.” The 2015 A.T. Kearney
Foreign Direct Investment Confidence Index.
Aaronson, Susan A. and Jean Pierre Chauffour. 2011. “The Wedding of Trade and Human Rights:
Marriage of Convenience or Permanent Match?” World Trade Organization, Discussion
Forum: World Trade Report 2011.
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of
Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91,
no. 5: 1369-1401.
Aghion, Philippe et al. 2005. “Competition and Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics: 701-28.
Amiti, Mary and Donald R. Davis. 2012. “Trade, Firms, and Wages: Theory and Evidence.” The
Review of Economic Studies 79, no.1: 1-36.
Antweiler, Werner, Brian R. Copeland, and M. Scott Taylor. 2001. “Is Free Trade Good for the
Environment?” American Economic Review 91, no. 4: 877-908.
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1962. “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing.Review of Economic
Studies 29: 155-73.
Atkin, David, Amit K. Khandelwal, and Adam Osman. 2014. “Exporting and Firm Performance:
Evidence from a Randomized Trial.” Working Paper 20690. Cambridge, Mass.: National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Aw, Bee Yan, Mark J. Roberts, and Daniel Yi Xu. 2008. “R&D Investments, Exporting, and the
Evolution of Firm Productivity.” American Economic Review 98, no. 2: 451-6.
Baier, Scott L. and Jeffrey H. Bergstrand. 2007. “Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase
Members’ International Trade?” Journal of International Economics 71, no. 1: 72-95.
Becker, Gary S. 1957. “The Economics of Discrimination.” The University of Chicago Press, 2
nd
edition.
Becker, Randy, Wayne Gray, and Jordan Marvakov. 2013. “NBER-CES Manufacturing Industry
Database.” Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bernard, Andrew B. and J. Bradford Jensen. 1995. “Exporters, Jobs, and Wages in U.S.
Manufacturing: 1976-1987.” Brookings Papers on Activity: Microeconomics 1995: 67-112.
____. 1997. Exporters, Skill Upgrading and the Wage GapJournal of International Economics
42, no. 1-2: 3-31.
____. 1999. “Exceptional Exporter Performance: Cause, Effect, or Both?” Journal of International
Economics 47, no. 1: 1-25.
____. 2004a. “Why Some Firms Export.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86, no. 2: 561-69.
____. 2004b. “Exporting and Productivity in the USA.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 20, no.
3: 343-57.
Bernard, Andrew B., J. Bradford Jensen, Stephen J. Redding, and Peter K. Schott. 2007. “Firms in
International Trade.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, no. 3: 105-130.
Bernard, Andrew B., J. Bradford Jensen, and Peter K. Schott. 2006. “Trade Costs, Firms and
Productivity.” Journal of Monetary Economics 53, no. 5: 917-37.
Bernard, Andrew B., Stephen J. Redding, and Peter K. Schott. 2011. “Multi-Product Firms and
Trade Liberalization.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126, no 3: 1271-1318.
49
Black, Sandra E. and Elizabeth Brainerd. 2004. “Importing Equality? The Impact of Globalization
on Gender Discrimination.” Industrial and Labor Review 57, no. 4: 540-59.
Bloom, Nicholas, Mirko Draca, and John Van Reenen. 2011. “Trade Induced Technical Change?
The Impact of Chinese Imports on Innovation, IT and Productivity.” Centre for Economic
Performance Discussion Paper no. 1000.
Bradford, Scott C., Paul L. E. Grieco, and Gary Clyde Hufbauer. 2005. “The Payoff to America from
Global Integration.” in C. Fred Bergsten ed The United States and the World Economy.
Institute for International Economics. Washington, DC.
Branstetter, Lee G., Raymond Fisman, and C. Fritz Foley. 2006. “Do Stronger Intellectual Property
Rights Increase International Technology Transfer? Empirical Evidence from U.S. Firm-
Level Panel Data.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, no. 1: 321-49.
Broda, Christian and David E. Weinstein. 2006. “Globalization and the Gains from Variety.” The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, no. 2: 541-85.
Bureau of International Labor Affairs. 2012. 2011 Findings on the Worst Forms of Child Labor. U.S.
Department of Labor.
____. 2013. 2012 Findings on the Worst Forms of Child Labor. U.S. Department of Labor.
____. 2014. 2013 Findings on the Worst Forms of Child Labor. U.S. Department of Labor.
Bustos, Paula. 2007. “The Impact of Trade on Technology Skill Upgrading Evidence from
Argentina.” Working Paper 1189. Department of Economics, Pompeu Fabra University.
____. 2011. “Trade Liberalization, Exports, and Technology Upgrading: Evidence on the Impact of
MERCOSUR on Argentinian Firms.” The American Economic Review 101, no. 1: 304-40.
Celasun, Oya, Gabriel Di Bella, Tim Mahedy, and Chris Papageorgiou. 2014. “The U.S.
Manufacturing Recovery: Uptick or Renaissance?” Working Paper 14/28. International
Monetary Fund.
Chandy, Laurence and Geoffrey Gertz. 2011. “Poverty in Numbers: The Changing State of Global
Poverty from 2005 to 2015.” Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Copeland, Brian R. and M. Scott Taylor. 2003. “Trade and the Environment.” Princeton University
Press.
Council of Economic Advisers. 2015a. Economic Report of the President. February.
Council of Economic Advisers. 2015b. “Trade Agreements and Outsourcing.” Issue Brief.
Davidson, Carl, Steven J. Matusz, and Andrei Shevchenko. 2008. “Globalization and Firm Level
Adjustment with Imperfect Labor Markets.” Journal of International Economics 75, no. 2:
295-309.
Davis, Donald R. and James Harrigan. 2011. “Good Jobs, Bad Jobs, and Trade Liberalization.”
Journal of International Economics 84, no. 1: 26-36.
De Loecker, Jan. 2007. “Do Exports Generate Higher Productivity? Evidence from Slovenia.”
Journal of International Economics 73, no. 1: 69-98.
De Loecker, Jan. 2013. “Detecting Learning by Exporting.” American Economic Journal:
Microeconomics 5, no. 3: 1-121.
De Loecker, Jan and Pinelopi K. Goldberg. 2014. “Firm Performance in a Global Market.” Annual
Review of Economics 6, no. 1: 201-27.
Distelhorst, Greg, Jens Hainmueller, and Richard M. Locke. 2014. “Does Lean Improve Labor
Standards? Management and Social Performance in the Nike Supply Chain.” Watson
Institute for International Studies Research Paper 2013-09.
50
Dewan, Sabina and Lucas Ronconi. 2014. “U.S. Free Trade Agreements and Enforcement of Labor
Law in Latin America.” IDB Working Paper Series No. IDB-WP-543.
Economic Research Service. 2013. “Effects of Trade on the U.S. Economy, Agricultural Trade
Multiplier.” U.S. Department of Agriculture.
Edmonds, Eric V. and Nina Pavcnik. 2005. “The Effect of Trade Liberalization on Child Labor.”
Journal of International Economics 65, no. 2: 401-19.
Eichengreen, Barry and David Leblang. 2006. “Democracy and Globalization.” Working Paper
12450. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Essaji, Azim, Gregory Sweeney, and Alexandros Kotsopoulos. 2010. “Equality through Exposure
to Imports? International Trade and the Racial Wage Gap.” Journal of Economic Policy
Reform 13, no. 4: 313-23.
Fajgelbaum, Pablo D. and Amit K. Khandelwal. 2014. “Measuring the Unequal Gains from Trade.”
Working Paper 20331. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Feyrer, James. 2009a. “Distance, Trade, and Income—The 1967 to 1975 Closing of the Suez Canal
as a Natural Experiment.” Working Paper 15557. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
____. 2009b. Trade and IncomeExploiting Time Series in Geography.” Working Paper 14910.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Frankel, Jeffrey A. and David Romer. 1999. “Does Trade Cause Growth?” American Economic
Review 90, no. 3: 379-99.
Frías, Judith A., David S. Kaplan, and Eric A. Verhoogen. 2009. “Exports and Wage Premia:
Evidence from Mexican Employer-Employee Data.” Columbia University, Department of
Economics.
Goldberg, Pinelopi K. and Nina Pavcnik. 2003. “The Response of the Informal Sector to Trade
Liberalization.” Journal of Development Economics 72, no. 2: 463-96.
Grether, Jean-Marie, Nicole A. Mathys, and Jaime De Melo. 2010. “Global Manufacturing SO2
Emissions: Does Trade Matter?” Review of World Economics 145, no. 4: 713-29.
Grossman, Gene M. and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2008. “Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of
Offshoring.” American Economic Review 98, no. 5: 1978-97.
Hanson, Gordon H. 2007. “Globalization, Labor Income, and Poverty in Mexico.” Globalization
and Poverty. The University of Chicago Press, 417-46.
Harrison, Ann, John McLaren, and Margaret McMillan. 2011. “Recent Perspectives on Trade and
Inequality.” Annual Review of Economics 3: 261-89.
Helpman, Elhanan, Oleg Itskhoki, and Stephen Redding. 2010. “Inequality and Unemployment in
a Global Economy.” Econometrica 78, no. 4: 1239-83.
Ibarra-Caton, Marilyn and Raymond J. Mataloni Jr. 2014. “Direct Investment Positions for 2013,
Country and Industry Detail.” Survey of Current Business, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Jensen, J. Bradford. 2011. Global Trade in Services: Fear, Facts, and Offshoring. Peterson Institute
for International Economics. Washington, D.C.
Kant, Immanuel. 1795. Perpetual Peace and Other Essays on Politics, History and Morals.
Kharas, Homi and Geoffrey Gertz. 2010. “The New Global Middle Class: A Cross-Over from West
to East.” in Cheng Li ed China’s Emerging Middle Class: Beyond Economic Transformation.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
51
Klein, Michael W., Christoph Moser, and Dieter M. Urban. 2010. “The Contribution of Trade to
Wage Inequality: the Role of Skill, Gender, and Nationality.” Working Paper 15985.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Lileeva, Alla and Daniel Trefler. 2010. “Improved Access to Foreign Markets Raises Plant-level
Productivity…For Some Plants.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, no. 3: 1051-99.
López-Córdova, J. Ernesto and Christopher M. Meissner. 2005. The Globalization of Trade and
Democracy, 1980-2000.” Working Paper 11117. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
MacDuffie, John Paul and Susan Helper. 1997. “Creating Lean Suppliers: Diffusing Lean
Production throughout the Supply Chain.” California Management Review 39, no. 4: 118-
51.
McCaig, Brian. 2011. “Exporting Out of Poverty: Provincial Poverty in Vietnam and U.S. Market
Access.” Journal of International Economics 85, no. 1: 102-113.
McCaig, Brian and Nina Pavcnik. 2014. “Export Markets and Labor Allocation in a Low-Income
Country.” Working Paper 20455. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate
Industry Productivity.” Econometrica 71, no. 6: 1695-1725.
Menezes-Filho, Naércio Aquino and Marc-Andreas Muendler. 2011. “Labor Reallocation
Response to Trade Reform.” Working Paper 17372. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Milanovic, Branko. 2013. “Global Income Inequality in Numbers: in History and Now.” Global
Policy 4, no. 2: 198-208.
Mostashari, Shalah M. 2010. “Expanding Variety of Goods Underscores Battle for Comparative
Advantage.” Economic Letter 5, no. 15. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas.
Nicholson, Jessica R. and Ryan Noonan. 2014. “Digital Economy and Cross-Border Trade: The
Value of Digitally-Deliverable Services.” U.S. Department of Commerce, Economics and
Statistics Administration.
Nordström, Håkan and Scott Vaughan. 1999. “Trade and Environment.” Special Studies 4. The
World Trade Organization.
Office of the Chief Economist. 2014. “Trade Agreements and U.S. Agriculture.” U.S. Department
of Agriculture.
Olney, William W. 2013. “A Race to the Bottom? Employment Protection and Foreign Direct
Investment.” Journal of International Economics 91, no. 2: 191-203.
Palley, Thomas I. 2005. “Labour Standards, Democracy, and Wages: Some Cross-Country
Evidence.” Journal of International Development. 17: 1-16.
Paz, Lourenço S. 2014. “The Impacts of Trade Liberalization on Informal Labor Markets: A
Theoretical and Empirical Evaluation of the Brazilian Case.” Journal of International
Economics 92, no. 2: 330-48.
Petri, Peter A., Michael G. Plummer, and Fan Zhai. 2012. The Trans-Pacific Partnership and Asia-
Pacific Integration: A Quantitative Assessment. Peterson Institute for International
Economics. Washington, D.C.
____. 2013. “Adding Japan and Korea to the TPP.” Unpublished manuscript, asiapacifictrade.org.
52
Riker, David. 2010. “Do Jobs in Export Industries Still Pay More? And Why?” Manufacturing and
Services Economics Brief no. 2, International Trade Administration, U.S. Department of
Commerce.
____. 2015. “Export-Intensive Industries Pay More on Average: An Update.” Office of Economics
Research Note No. 2015-04A. U.S. International Trade Commission.
Riker, David and Brandon Thurner. 2011. “Weekly Earnings in Export-Intensive U.S. Services
Industries.” Manufacturing and Services Economics Brief no. 4, International Trade
Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce.
Romer, Paul. 1994. “New Goods, Old Theory, and the Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions.”
Journal of Development Economics 43, no. 1: 5-38.
Salem, Samira and Faina Rozental. 2012. “Labor Standards and Trade: A Review of Recent
Empirical Evidence.” Journal of International Commerce and Economics 4, no. 2: 63-98.
Schank, Thorsten, Claus Schnabel, and Joachim Wagner. 2004. “Exporting Firms Do Not Pay
Higher Wages, Ceteris Paribus. First Evidence from Linked Employer-Employee Data.” IZA
Discussion Paper No. 1185.
Sykes, Alan O. 2003. “International Trade and Human Rights: An Economic Perspective.” John M.
Olin Law & Economics Working Paper No. 188. Chicago, Illinois.: The Law School of the
University of Chicago.
Teich, Sorin T. and Fady F. Faddoul. 2013. “Lean ManagementThe Journey from Toyota to
Healthcare.” Rambam Maimonides Medical Journal 4, no. 2.
Topalova, Petia. 2007. “Trade Liberalization, Poverty and Inequality: Evidence from Indian
Districts.” Globalization and Poverty. The University of Chicago Press, 291-336.
____. 2010. “Factor Immobility and Regional Impacts of Trade Liberalization: Evidence on
Poverty from India.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 2, no. 4: 1-41.
Van Biesebroeck, Johannes. 2005. “Exporting Raises Productivity in Sub-Saharan African
Manufacturing Firms.” Journal of International Economics 67, no. 2: 373-91.
Verhoogen, Eric. 2008. “Trade, Quality Upgrading, and Wage Inequality in the Mexican
Manufacturing Sector.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, no. 2: 489-530.
Yeaple, Stephen Ross. 2005. “A Simple Model of Firm Heterogeneity, International Trade, and
Wages.” Journal of International Economics 65, no. 1: 1-20.